Colonial Education, Political Elites, and Regional Political Inequality in Africa

AuthorJoan Ricart-Huguet
Published date01 December 2021
Date01 December 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0010414021997176
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414021997176
Comparative Political Studies
© The Author(s) 2021
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0010414021997176
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Article
Colonial Education,
Political Elites, and
Regional Political
Inequality in Africa
Joan Ricart-Huguet1
Abstract
Political elites tend to favor their home region when distributing resources.
But what explains how political power is distributed across a country’s
regions to begin with? Explanations of cabinet formation focus on short-
term strategic bargaining and some emphasize that ministries are allocated
equitably to minimize conflict. Using new data on the cabinet members
(1960–2010) of 16 former British and French African colonies, I find that
some regions have been systematically much more represented than others.
Combining novel historical and geospatial records, I show that this regional
political inequality derives not from colonial-era development in general
but from colonial-era education in particular. I argue that post-colonial
ministers are partly a byproduct of civil service recruitment practices among
European administrators that focused on levels of literacy. Regional political
inequality is an understudied pathway through which colonial legacies impact
distributive politics and unequal development in Africa today.
JEL: F54, I26, N37, N47
Keywords
political elites, cabinets, colonialism, education, regional inequality, Africa
1Loyola University Maryland, Baltimore, USA
Corresponding Author:
Joan Ricart-Huguet, Department of Political Science, Loyola University Maryland, 4501 North
Charles Street, Baltimore, MD 21210-2601, USA.
Email: jricart-huguet@loyola.edu
997176
CPSXXX10.1177/0010414021997176Comparative Political StudiesRicart-Huguet
research-article
2021
2021, Vol. 54(14) 2546 –2580
Ricart-Huguet 2547
2 Comparative Political Studies 00(0)
In a political system where nearly every adult may vote but where knowledge,
wealth, social position, access to officials, and other resources are unequally
distributed, who actually governs?
Dahl (1961, p. 1)
Introduction
Political elites fundamentally shape political representation, conflict, and the
distribution of resources. Existing research shows that presidents and minis-
ters disproportionately favor their home region, especially in less democratic
countries (Andre et al., 2018; Hodler & Raschky, 2014; Kramon & Posner,
2016). As Bates (1974, p. 470) argued, “in the political arena, it is not just
power that is at stake, but also the benefit which power can bring.” In this
article, I begin by showing that political power is unequally distributed within
African countries: some regions are heavily over-represented in cabinets
while others are underrepresented. This presents an important puzzle: What
explains the regional distribution of political power to begin with? More spe-
cifically, what explains the share of ministers hailing from each of a country’s
regions or districts?1
Existing literature offers two explanations of cabinet formation: regional
favoritism and regional balancing. Regional favoritism emphasizes that the
making of the cabinet is the result of short-term regional and ethnic strategic
considerations such as patronage (Arriola, 2009). In 1970s Uganda, Colonel
Idi Amin filled his cabinet with people from West Nile, his home region. In
Côte d’Ivoire, Houphouët-Boigny’s cabinets favored the Baoulé, his ethnic
group. Meanwhile, regional balancing posits that “representation in a presi-
dent’s cabinet [. . .] has to appear to be equitable” (Keller, 1983, p. 259) to
deter conflict. “President Kenyatta’s announcement of three ministerial
appointments from Nyanza province in July 1969 was clearly calculated to
appease the aggrieved feelings of the Luo people following the assassination
of Tom Mboya, one of Kenya’s founding fathers” (Rothchild, 1970, p. 605).
Consistent with this example, Francois et al. (2015, p. 472) show that ethnic
group shares in the cabinet are correlated with population shares.
I contend that both explanations are incomplete and possibly shortsighted
because they only examine the short-term strategy of politicians (Laver &
Shepsle, 1996), ignore the historical origins of elites, and cannot account for
the persistent regional political inequality that I uncover. Figure 1 shows the
percentages of minister-years (most ministers stay in power for more than
1 year) by district in Uganda and Senegal between 1960 and 2010.2 If regional
balancing produced equitable distributions of minister-year shares, then the
2548 Comparative Political Studies 54(14)
Ricart-Huguet 3
distribution would be uniform (the left graphs would be flat) or proportional
to population (the right graphs would be flat). Neither is the case. Some dis-
tricts have systematically punched above their weight since independence
and others below. Averaged over 1960 to 2010, 14% of the minister-years in
Uganda were born in Ankole district despite its population being only 9% of
Uganda’s total. 14% of the minister-years in Senegal were born in Saint Louis
even though the district comprises less than 2% of Senegal’s population.
Regional favoritism alone cannot explain the patterns in Figure 1 either.
Ankole district in Uganda is over-represented partly because President
Museveni (1986–) was born there. However, patronage-type explanations
beg the question of why leaders hail from one district or another in the first
place. Further, other districts beyond the president’s are over-represented.
Regional favoritism cannot explain the case of Saint Louis either: no
Senegalese president was born there. More generally, and in spite of politi-
cal instability in many East and West African countries, district representa-
tion in the 1960s correlates with district representation in the 2000s
(
ρ
= 0.46 ), thus suggesting underlying and persistent inequalities in politi-
cal representation.
0 5 10 15 20
Percentage
Karamoja
Mubende
Teso
Bunyoro
Masaka
Lango
Budama
Westnile
Central
Toro
Acholi
Busoga
Kigezi
Ankole
Mengo
minister share
-4 -2 0 2 4 6
Percentage
Mubende
Busoga
Masaka
Lango
Karamoja
Central
Toro
Westnile
Teso
Bunyoro
Mengo
Acholi
Budama
Kigezi
Ankole
minister share - population share
Uganda
0 5 10 15
Percentage
Bakel
Dagana
Hautegambie
Podor
Tambacounda
Matam
Tivaouane
Baol
Louga
Casamance
Sinesaloum
Saintlouis
Dakar
Thies
minister share
-5 0 5 10 15
Percentage
Dakar
Sinesaloum
Baol
Tivaouane
Dagana
Bakel
Podor
Matam
Tambacounda
Hautegambie
Casamance
Louga
Thies
Saintlouis
minister share - population share
Senegal
Figure 1. Minister-shares by district of birth (1960–2010 average).
The left figures show the percentage of minister-years born in each colonial district (1960–
2010 average). The right figures subtract district population shares (1960–2010 average) from
that percentage.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT