Collusion with limited product comparability

AuthorNicolas Roos
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12242
Published date01 September 2018
Date01 September 2018
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.49, No. 3, Fall 2018
pp. 481–503
Collusion with limited product comparability
Nicolas de Roos
Weexamine the effect of limited product comparability on the viability of collusion. Firms choose
messages to influence consumer product comparison. The cartel hinders transparency on the
equilibrium path and seeks it for optimal punishment. Five conditions are each sufficient to
ensure obfuscation aids collusion: if firms can mix over messages or commit to messages, if
messages are informative,or if an individual firm or the cartel can control comparability. We also
analyze the impact of message differentiation and complexity for optimal messages, and identify
a key role for the convexity or concavity of comparison probabilities in these features.
1. Introduction
The task faced by the consumer in a standard market setting is Herculean, involving the
evaluation and comparison of a vast array of multidimensional products. Decisions made by
firms often complicate this task. For example, competing retail products may display different
units of measurement for prices or quantities; headline airfares may omit additional charges
relating to baggage, seat selection, credit card fees, and taxes; mobile phone plans, insurance
contracts, and credit cards incorporate contingencies that are difficult to assess; the compatibility
of electronic goods with complementary products may be hard to evaluate; and firms may even
make exaggerated or inaccurate claims about their products. It is not surprising that consumers
are sometimes unable to compare all available products, a fact long appreciated bymarketers and
regulators (Piccione and Spiegler, 2012).
A consumer faced with a product choice complicated by the decisions made by competing
firms could be forgiven for suspecting a conspiracy to soften market competition. To date, a
growing literature on obfuscation in oligopoly has presumed the opposite.1Rather than examine
the collective incentive for obfuscation, the literature has focused on the unilateral incentive of
each firm to obfuscate. Given that repeated interaction is the norm in oligopoly, this omission
is surprising. The logic is articulated concisely by Ellison and Wolitzky (2012): “Why collude
University of Sydney; nicolas.deroos@sydney.edu.au.
I am grateful to Murali Agastya, Mark Armstrong, Simona Fabrizi,Steffen Lippert, Jonathan Newton, Kunal Sengupta, and
Jidong Zhou; two anonymous referees; participants at the Australasian Economic Theory Workshop(Monash University,
2016), the University of Queensland Industrial Organisation Workshop(2016), the Asia-Pacific Industrial Organisation
Conference (University of Melbourne, 2016), the Conference of the European Association for Research in Industrial
Economics (Maastricht University, 2017), the conference of the Mannheim Centre for Competition and Innovation
(2018); and seminar audiences at the University of Giessen (2017) and the University of D¨
usseldorf (2017) for valuable
comments and encouragement.
1See Spiegler (2016) and Grubb (2015) for recent discussions of related literature.
C2018, The RAND Corporation. 481
482 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
on obfuscation rather than just colluding on price?” In this article, we provide a simple answer.
Coordinating on obfuscation may relax the incentive constraints of a cartel, enabling effective
collusion on price.
Weadapt the consumer choice framework of Spiegler (2016), in which obfuscation operates
through limited product comparability, to examine the coordination problem of a price-fixing
cartel with opportunities for obfuscation. This framework has the virtue that it can illustrate a
range of models of obfuscation, including the manipulation of product description formats (Carlin,
2009; Piccione and Spiegler, 2012; Chioveanu and Zhou, 2013), the emphasis or shrouding of
product attributes (Gabaix and Laibson, 2006), and consumer search (Varian,1980). We examine
the conditions under which collusion is aided by obfuscation, and the optimal form of obfuscation
for the cartel.
In our model, nfirms simultaneously choose a price and a “marketing message” for a
homogeneous product overan infinite horizon.2Marketing messages are broadly defined to include
any aspect of the marketing or description of a product that may influence consumer product
comparison, including the units of measurement, the specification of contingencies, or even the
language or jargon employed byfir ms to frame their products. The vector of marketingmessages
stochastically influences the propensity of consumers to make binary product comparisons.
A product is eliminated from the consumer choice set only if there is a cheaper comparable
alternative. Thus, the message vector affectsconsumer choice by influencing the set of comparable
product pairs.
The fundamental problem for any cartel is to maintain internal incentives for cooperation.
The cartel’s incentive constraints depend on the collusive profits promised by cartel policies,
the profits available to a firm deviating from cartel policies, and the severity of punishment the
cartel is able to inflict on a deviator. Limited comparability introduces a trade-off by impacting
both deviation and punishment payoffs. The cartel can manipulate this trade-off through careful
message choice. A deviation involving marginallyundercutting the cartel price is more profitable
the greater the number of comparable products. Cartel members therefore have an incentive to
limit the transparency of the message profile on the equilibrium path to minimize the possible
gains to deviation. By contrast, the severity of punishment depends on the ability of the cartel to
reconfigure the message vector to facilitate product comparison. A deviating firm has the opposite
incentives,and therefore the choice of messages can be framed as a battle for t ransparencybetween
a deviator and the remaining cartel members.
In the battle for transparency, several factors tilt the balance of power between deviator and
cartel, and thus determine the critical discount factor of the cartel. First, the deviator has an
advantage as a Stackelberg follower: she has an opportunity to respond to the equilibrium path
messages of the cartel. Thus, despite our focus on simultaneous play, it is as if a deviator moves
second. The deviator enjoys a similar privileged position for the purposes of punishment. If this
advantage can be neutralized, then limited comparability is weakly beneficial to the cartel. We
establish a number of separate conditions which do exactly that. If mixedstrategies are available,
if the cartel can commit to messages, or if any firm or the cartel as a whole is able to control
comparability, then limited comparability is weakly beneficial.
Second, there is an asymmetry in the trade-off between deviation and punishment payoffs.
A single comparable product eliminates punishment payoffs, whereas complete comparability is
needed to maximize deviation profits. In the special case where either all products or no products
are comparable, the trade-off balances and, providing the Stackelberg follower advantage of
the deviator can be neutralized, the sustainability of collusion matches a perfect information
benchmark. This result applies directly to well-known models of consumer search. In the model
of sales of Varian (1980), consumers are either perfectly informed or completely uninformed
about prices; the sustainability of collusion is thus identical to the benchmark. This result also
explains a sharp distinction between two-firm cartels and larger cartels. With twofir ms, it follows
2Webor rowthis ter minologyfrom Spiegler (2014).
C
The RAND Corporation 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT