Collusion with intertemporal price dispersion

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12309
AuthorVladimir Smirnov,Nicolas de Roos
Published date01 March 2020
Date01 March 2020
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.51, No. 1, Spring 2020
pp. 158–188
Collusion with intertemporal price
dispersion
Nicolas de Roos
and
Vladimir Smirnov
We develop a theory of optimal collusive intertemporal price dispersion. Dispersion clouds
consumer price awareness, encouraging firms to coordinate on dispersed prices. Our theory
generates a collusive rationale for price cycles and sales. Patient firms can support optimal
collusion at the monopoly price. For less patient firms, monopoly prices must be punctuated with
fleeting sales. The most robust structure involves price cycles that resemble Edgeworth cycles.
Low consumer attentiveness enhances the effectiveness of price dispersion by reducing the payoff
to deviations involving price reductions. However, for sufficiently low attentiveness, price rises
are also a concern.
1. Introduction
The nagging presence of competitors is an inescapable fact of life for most firms. To
understand pricing behavior, wemust therefore consider the implications of repeated interaction.
The theory of repeated games offers some insights; notably, repeated play opens up opportunities
for punishments and rewards, permitting higher prices to be supported. However, nontrivial price
dynamics are also a common outcome of repeated play.For example, using scanner data covering
1.4 million goods in 54 geographic markets, Kaplan and Menzio (2015) find that close to half the
University of Sydney; nicolas.deroos@sydney.edu.au,vladimir.smirnov@sydney.edu.au.
Weare grateful to Murali Agastya, Jim Albrecht, Mark Ar mstrong, Michelle Bergemann, SergeyIzmalkov, Eric Maskin,
Mark Melatos, Ariel Pakes,David Pearce, Debraj Rey, John Romalis, AbhijitSengupta, Kunal Sengupta, Andy Skrzypacz,
Juuso V¨
alim¨
aki, Jeroen van de Ven, Andrew Wait, and anonymous referees for useful comments, suggestions, and
encouragement. We thank attentive seminar audiences at the University of Bielefeld (2013), the Australian National
University (2013), the University of New South Wales (2013), the University of Sydney (2013), the University of
Queensland (2013), Georgetown University (2014), the Stern School of Business at NYU (2014), Harvard University
(2014), Boston College (2014), New York University(2014), the Free University of Amsterdam (2014), the University of
Amsterdam (2014), the University of Mannheim (2014), the University ofGroningen (2014), the New Economic School
(2016), and Monash University (2017).
158 C2020, The RAND Corporation.
DE ROOS AND SMIRNOV / 159
variation in prices is intertemporal.1An even larger role is typically played by intertemporal price
variation in retail gasoline markets subject to regular price cycles known as Edgeworth cycles.2
The rationale for these pricing patterns is not obvious in a repeated game setting. If the threat
of punishment is available, whydon’t firms employ it to support the highest feasible fixed price?
Complicated pricing patterns may be both more difficult to coordinate on and less profitable.
In this article, we develop a theory of coordinated price dispersion that provides an intuitive
explanation. Our theory rationalizes commonly observed pricing patterns including sales, price
cycles, and fixed prices. Our starting point is the consumer.
Pretend for a moment that you are a consumer. Think of a few products that may be in your
shopping basket; for example, milk, coffee, petrol, breakfast cereals. What is the current price of
these items at your local store? What is the current price at other stores? Would you recognize
a bargain? Your answers to these questions may vary by product; frequency of purchase and
prominence of display are obvious factors. We conjecture that the complexity of pricing patterns
also plays a role. A consumer who routinely observes a single price may become accustomed to
that price and recognize immediately a departure from this simple pricing pattern. By contrast,
complicated price paths are more difficult to absorb, making price changes less obvious.3If
consumer price perceptions are influenced by pricing patterns in this manner, they may be ripe
for manipulation by firms. We consider the optimal pricing problem of a cartel faced with
this prospect.
In our model, firms engage in repeated simultaneous price competition for a homogeneous
product. Weseek the optimal collusive pricing strategy.As with any cartel, the immediate problem
is to maintain incentives for internal discipline. Each cartel member trades off the short-term
incentive to deviate and raise current profits against the long-term benefit of receiving lucrative
cartel payoffs. We introduce imperfectly attentive consumers to this standard environment. The
premise of the model is that the set of prices each consumer is aware of depends on the recent
history of prices. Prices that are historically low are included in each consumer’s awareness set
for sure, whereas other prices are in the awareness set only with positive probability. Consumers
then choose the cheapest offering in their awareness set. This introduces a novel consideration
for the cartel. The cartel’s price path determines the prices consumers experience, giving the
cartel the ability to manipulate consumer awareness, with direct consequences for the incentive
constraints of the cartel. The optimal dynamic price path for the cartel emerges as a trade-off
between profitability and obfuscation.4
In addition to cartel manipulation, innate market characteristics influence a consumer’s
tendency to perceive and recall price information. We parameterize our model by the level of
consumer attentiveness, ranging from perfect awareness to complete inattentiveness. At one
extreme, our specification approaches the Bertrand model and obfuscation is futile. Consumers
are aware of all prices and an undercutting firm captures the whole market independent of the
1Kaplan and Menzio (2015) use the Kilts-Nielsen Consumer Panel Dataset, which records the shopping behavior
of approximately 50,000 consumers overthe period 2004–2009, and contains over 300 million transactions. The authors
decompose the variation in prices into that due to variation across stores, across products at a given store, and across
transactions over time for a specific product-store pair,finding that inter temporal variationin prices accounts for close to
half the variation.
2For example, in the Perth gasoline market studied byWang (2009) and de Roos and Katayama (2013), a similar
decomposition revealsthat in 2003, approximately 54% of the variation in retail margins is accounted for by intertemporal
variation in margins at a given retail station. If we condition onlyon stations par ticipating in the cycle (the majority of
stations), this rises to around 97%. Further details are available on request.
3This line of reasoning is supported by the concepts of rehearsal and associativenessthat Mullainathan (2002) draws
from the literature on memory research. Taken together,these two principles may imply a constant price would become
a well-established reference for comparison, whereas an intertemporally dispersed price path might be less amenable to
these memory processes.
4Throughout the article, we use the term obfuscation to refer to the cartel’s manipulation of consumer awareness
sets. This choice of language is in the spirit of Ellison and Ellison (2009), who use the term to refer to the manipulation
of rationally optimizing consumers subject to search frictions.
C
The RAND Corporation 2020.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT