Collective Bargaining and Innovation in Germany: A Case of Cooperative Industrial Relations?

Date01 January 2017
AuthorJohn T. Addison,Lutz Bellmann,Katalin Evers,Paulino Teixeira
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irel.12165
Published date01 January 2017
Collective Bargaining and Innovation in
Germany: A Case of Cooperative Industrial
Relations?
*
JOHN T. ADDISON, PAULINO TEIXEIRA, KATALIN EVERS and
LUTZ BELLMANN
At the level of theory, the effect of collective bargaining on innovation is con-
tested. The large proponderance of the U.S. evidence clearly points to adverse
effects, but other-country experience suggests that certain industrial-relations sys-
tems, or the wider regulatory apparatus, might even tip the balance in favor of
unions. Our pooled cross- section and difference-in-differences estimates provide
some weak evidence that German collective bargaining inhibits innovation. How-
ever, in conjunction with workplace representation, there is the suggestion that it
might actually foster innovative activity.
Introduction
The topic of collective bargaining and investment in intangible (and tangi-
ble) capital has been the subject of considerable controversy for a number of
years. The debate remains unsettled, although theory has tended to look with
more favor upon the union entity if it is located in an appropriateinstitu-
tional setting. Theory has in one sense been channeled in this direction by
empirical research pointing to a sharp dichotomy between North American
ndings that are almost invariably negative in respect of the union impact on
innovation capital and European research that generally points to an absence
of signicant associations once one proceeds much beyond the raw correla-
tions in the data.
*The authorsafliations are, respectively, Durham University Business School, Durham, England, and Moore
School of Business, University of South Carolina, Columbia, South Carolina. E-mail: ecceaddi@moore.sc.edu;
Universidade de Coimbra, Coimbra, Portugal. E-mail: pteixeira@fe.uc.pt; Institut f
ur Abeitsmarkt- und Berufs-
forschung, Bundesagentur f
ur Arbeit, N
urnberg, Germany. E-mail: Katalin.Evers@iab.de; Friedrich-Alexan-
der-Universit
at Erlangen-N
urnberg, and Institut f
ur Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung, Bundesagentur f
ur
Arbeit, N
urnberg, Germany. E-mail: Lutz.Bellmann@iab.de.
Addison gratefully acknowledges nancial support from the Riegel and Emory Human Resource Center of the
University of South Carolina.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, Vol. 56, No. 1 (January 2017). ©2016 Regents of the University of California
Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK.
73
In the present paper, we focus on the innovative activities of German estab-
lishments over the 6-year observation window 20072012. Our measure of
innovation is the actual (or successful) introduction of some product or process
innovation (although we shall also investigate failure to innovate). Apart from
allowing us to consider a new output indicator, our choice of Germany was
predicated on that nations unique structure of cooperative industrial relations,
early research seeming to offer some conrmation of the benets of coopera-
tion provided the level of union density is not excessive.
We use both extensive descriptive analysis and regression techniques to evalu-
ate the role of different institutional arrangements on innovation, while controlling
for a wide array of establishment-level observables. We also tackle unobserved
establishment heterogeneity by constructing different establishment subsamples
and then investigating differences in changes in the incidence of innovation using
appropriate comparison groups of innovating and noninnovating establishments in
combination with collective bargaining (and works council) switchers and collec-
tive bargaining stayers in a difference-in-differences framework. This approach to
isolating the causal effect of labor institutions, using changes in collective bargain-
ing status as the main identication vehicle, is new in this literature. (For another
approach, see the discussion of Bradley, Kim, and Tian [2015] below.)
The structure of the paper is as follows. First, we provide a comprehensive
statement of the theory of collective bargaining/unionism and innovation with
a view to justifying consideration of the German case, while deriving a set of
more targeted hypotheses related to that nation. Second, we examine the
empirical evidence on innovation, with the goal of drawing a distinction
between the North American evidence and the rest before examining a still
sparse extant German literature by way of scene-setting. Third, we review the
unique dataset used in this inquiry and introduce the key innovation measures
and explanatory variables. Fourth, we present a set of descriptive results on
the frequency and continuity of the different types of innovative activity and
describe the unconditional and conditional (on union/worker representation)
probabilities of an establishment having a particular type of innovation. Fifth,
our detailed ceteris paribus results are presented, together with robustness
checks. A summary concludes, the burden of which is that German collective
bargaining is not generally to be construed as inhibiting innovation and may
indeed prove benecial when accompanied by workplace codetermination.
Theoretical Considerations
Theory suggests that collective bargaining can have positive as well as
negative effects on innovation. In the traditional model, the union-set wage is
74 / JOHN T. ADDISON,PAULINO TEIXEIRA,KATALIN EVERS AND LUTZ BELLMANN
represented as an exogenous change in the price of labor, the rm in response
adjusting employment along its labor-demand curve. In this case, the union
premium or tax is levied on labor. Union rms duly substitute away from
expensive labor. The net effect is unclear. It depends on the degree of substi-
tutability between capital and labor and the magnitude of the scale effect as
the premium lters through into higher product prices and output falls.
By contrast, the more modern view is that unions tax capital, that rms
respond unambiguously by cutting tangible and intangible capital investments,
and that the wage is endogenous. The idea is that unions expropriate part of
the quasi-rents that form part of the normal (i.e., competitive) returns to capital
but which are vulnerable to capture once investment in specialized plant and
equipment and research and development (R&D) has been made. We note par-
enthetically that R&D expenditures have been used in the literature as a key
indicator of the asset specicity of an investment (see Cavanaugh 1998).
Familiarly, such assets will continue in use as long they earn a return above
their alternative use; the more specic the asset, the bigger the scope for union
rent seeking. Of course, with the relation-specic capital in situ, higher wages
are unlikely to inuence the use of the asset, but rms will anticipate reduced
returns to such capital and invest less.
This is the so-called hold-upproblem, rst analyzed by Grout (1984). In
the simple one-shot two-stage game summarized by Menezes-Filho and van
Reenen (2003: 296), the rm rst chooses a level of capital (either high or
low) and in the next round the union chooses the wage (high/low). By back-
ward induction, the union will always choose a high wage in the second stage
and, knowing this, the rm will always choose a low investment strategy at
the rst stage. Further, the union tax on investment will vary directly with the
specicity of the asset and its longevity. The tax would vanish were the union
able to commit itself to a low-wage strategy by posting a bond or hostage to a
third party, or where there is bargaining over investment as well as wages.
1
However, collective bargaining is repeated over time rather than being a
one-shot exercise and, abstracting from an end-game scenario (Lawrence and
Lawrence 1985), repeated games offer a solution to the hold-up problem
because opportunistic behavior can in principle be appropriately punished
(e.g., van der Ploeg 1987). An important issue in the literature has been the
degree to which unions discount the future. In particular, it has been argued
that because union members do not have property rights in the union they will
be rationally myopic and discount the future at a higher rate than shareholders.
This tendency will be reinforced by the greater inuence of older workers in
1
We ignore for the moment the potential hold-up problem on the part of the employer.
Collective Bargaining and Innovation in Germany /75

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT