Coalition Building in Direct Democracy Campaigns

Published date01 March 2005
DOI10.1177/1532673X04272429
Date01 March 2005
AuthorMathew Manweller
Subject MatterArticles
10.1177/1532673X04272429AMERICAN POLITICS RESEARCH / MARCH 2005Manweller / COALITION BUILDING IN DIRECT DEMOCRACY
COALITION BUILDING IN
DIRECT DEMOCRACY CAMPAIGNS
MATHEW MANWELLER
Central Washington University
Commonto many social movement studies is the argument that ideological heterogeneity causes
organizationaldilemmas. Yet, few scholars consider,let alone test, the impact of ideological het-
erogeneity on direct democracycampaigns (DDCs). Drawing from the extant social movements
literature,I arguethat DDCs functionlike short-term socialmovements. Based on in-depth inter-
views of initiative activists, and in some cases participant-observation opportunities, I conclude
that ideological heterogeneity is also a contributing cause of DDC failure. Ideological heteroge-
neity within DDCs either results in factionalism that wastes time and resources, or the devel-
opment of homogeneous groups that pursue policies unacceptable to the median voter. I also
conclude that ideological heterogeneity is more destructive to DDCs than social movements.
Whereas social movementscan adapt over time, DDCs must achieve a singular electoral victory,
within a specific electoral cycle, in order to succeed. Therefore, time constraintsmake faction-
alism more problematic for DDCs.
Keywords: direct democracy; social movements; initiative process; ideological heterogene-
ity; state and local government
Most scholars agree that the modern era of direct democracy began
in 1978 when Howard Jarvis and Paul Gann successfully passed Cali-
fornia’s Proposition 13. Their tax rollback initiative sparked a series
of copycat initiatives across the West and catalyzed other activists to
realize the initiative process’s potential effectiveness. The frequency
of initiatives qualifying for the ballot (butnot necessarily passing) has
grown steadily since the late 1970s,1especially in western states such
as Oregon, Colorado, California, and Washington.
Direct democracy refers to the initiative, referendum, and recall
processes present in most states’constitutions.2The process offers cit-
izens the ability to propose and pass statutes and constitutional
amendments (initiatives), reject legislation passed or suggested by the
AMERICAN POLITICS RESEARCH, Vol. 33 No. 2, March 2005 246-282
DOI: 10.1177/1532673X04272429
© 2005 Sage Publications
246
legislature (referenda), and recall elected officials(recall). Unlike leg-
islation developed in state legislatures, the content of initiatives is
completely controlled by the sponsors of the measure. Other than
judicial review, there are no checks and balances such as a guberna-
torial veto or a committee chairperson’spigeonhole. In addition, once
supporters collect a single signature, the content of the measure
cannot be amended (unless supporters agree to start the signature-
collection process anew). In the past few decades, direct democracy
campaigns (DDCs) have been used to influence state-level policy
related to animal rights, drug use and punishment, education, the
death penalty, abortion, taxes, campaign finance reform, term limits,
and gun control (Waters, 2003).
A considerable body of research has examined the policy impact of
successful DDCs. Matsusaka (1995) records that states with direct
democracy have lower tax rates and lower spending levels. There is
conflicting evidence on direct democracy’s impact on public policy.
Gerber (1996, 1999) argues that direct democracy states adopt poli-
cies closer to the median voter on issues such as abortion, the death
penalty,and gay rights. However, Lascher,Hagen, and Rochlin (1996)
counter that governments in direct democracy states are no more re-
sponsive to public opinion than purely representative states. Eule
(1990) and Donovan and Bowler(1998) suggest direct democracy can
be dangerous to minorities. Gerber, Lupia, McCubbins, and Kiewiet
(2001) argue that the policy impact of initiatives depends on whether
there is a principal agency dilemma involved. However, despite the
considerable research on the impact of initiatives, very little research
has examined why some DDCs succeed whereas others fail. Given
that DDCs can have a significant impact on public policy, variables
that affect success or failure are important to understand.
It is essential to clarify early what is meant by “initiative failure.”
DDCs have three stages: ballot access, electoral campaign, and legal
defense. DDCs can fail at all three stages. (a) Initiatives may fail to
make the ballot. The leadership of a movement may fail to agree on
ballot language, or they may fail to acquire the required signatures. (b)
Initiatives may make the ballot but then fail to garner a majority vote.
(c) Initiatives may make the ballot, win an electoral majority, butthen
suffer invalidation by judicial review.
Manweller / COALITION BUILDING IN DIRECT DEMOCRACY 247
Although there is almost no literature examining how often DDCs
fail to qualify an initiative for the ballot, there has been some research
examining DDCs’success rates. Waters (2003) explains that approxi-
mately 48% of initiatives pass whereas 52% lose at the ballot box.3
Miller (1999, 2001) highlights that 54% of successful initiatives are
challenged in court and about 55% of those challenges result in a par-
tial or complete judicial invalidation.4But very little research has ex-
amined why DDCs fail. Broder (2000) suggests that money has a sig-
nificant impact on whether a DDC is successful. However, not all
spending is created equal. A majority of studies suggest that campaign
money has a greater ability to defeat an initiative than to ensure its pas-
sage. That is, money spent opposing initiatives is more effective than
money spent supporting them (Garrett & Gerber, 2001; Lowenstein,
1982; Zisk, 1987). Bowler and Donovan (1998) show that voters fac-
ing significant information costs about initiatives will adopt a risk-
averse approach and simply vote “no.” Karp (1998) argues that elite
opposition to initiatives increases their likelihood of failure. McCuan,
Bowler, Donovan,and Fernandez (1998) suggest the absence of cam-
paign professionals within a DDC increases the likelihood of failure.
The same four scholars also suggest that the type of coalition (broad
vs. diffuse) a DDC mobilizes will affect the likelihood of success.
They argue that initiatives pursuing benefits for special interests or
narrow constituencies fail at a higher rate than initiatives pursuing
benefits for broad coalitions (majoritarian politics). However, it is
important to note that most research examines the dynamics of exter-
nal influences. This article suggests that we need to examine the inter-
nal dynamics of initiative coalitions to add to our existing knowledge
of why so many DDCs fail.
IDEOLOGICAL HETEROGENEITY IN
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS
The existing social movement literature offers some insight into
how this research might proceed. Scholars examining social move-
ments have long studied the internal dynamics of organizations and
movements, and they offer a considerable body of knowledge on why
some movements fail. Common to most of these studies is the argu-
248 AMERICAN POLITICS RESEARCH / MARCH 2005

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT