Choosing a Lesser Evil: Partisanship, Labor, and Corporate Taxation under Globalization

Date01 September 2021
DOI10.1177/1065912920916556
AuthorZhiyuan Wang
Published date01 September 2021
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/1065912920916556
Political Research Quarterly
2021, Vol. 74(3) 571 –586
© 2020 University of Utah
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1065912920916556
journals.sagepub.com/home/prq
Article
Introduction
Leftist governments prefer higher corporate tax rates.
However, current scholarship only provides inconclusive
and mixed empirical support for this policy preference
(Basinger and Hallerberg 2004; Garrett 1998; Hays 2003;
Inclan, Quinn, and Shapiro 2001; Kumar and Quinn
2012; Shin 2017; Swank and Steinmo 2002). As a matter
of fact, worldwide corporate tax rates have converged
downwardly for the past three decades (Devereux,
Griffith, and Klemm 2002; Rodrik 1997; Slemrod 2004).
Paradoxically, this trend seems to go hand in hand with
the global rise of leftist governments since the 1990s
(Figure 1). If we look at individual countries, leftist gov-
ernments have witnessed cuts in corporate tax rates
almost everywhere, from Denmark, France, and South
Africa, to Sri Lanka, India, China, Uruguay, and Canada.
Then, what explains this puzzling occurrence? I intend
this study to explore answers to this question.
Globalization accelerates downward policy conver-
gence among states, as it significantly externalizes the
effects of domestic policy changes (e.g., Basinger and
Hallerberg 2004; Cao 2010; Lee and Strang 2006;
Swank 2006). As one constitutive feature of globaliza-
tion, capital flows at the global level and profoundly
affects a state’s economy (International Monetary Fund
2000). States join a fierce competition for this scarce
resource. Capital-friendly policies that help states sur-
vive the competition forces their convergence across
borders. For example, when states who compete for
capital restrict labor rights to lower the cost of labor in
the hope of attracting and retaining investment, others in
the same competition feel pressured to follow suit
(Davies and Vadlamannati 2013; Mosley 2011).1
However, not all governments can make this type of
policy move because the political costs of doing so are
unbearably high. It is especially true for leftist govern-
ments: reducing labor rights protection has a direct neg-
ative impact on their constituencies. Therefore, in the
face of this downward pressure, leftist governments will
look for policy alternatives that can achieve the goals
that diminished labor rights protection is expected to
accomplish, among which lowering corporate tax rates
is a competitive one. Specifically, I argue that when it is
politically unfeasible for leftist governments to restrict
916556PRQXXX10.1177/1065912920916556Political Research QuarterlyWang
research-article2020
1University of Florida, Gainesville, USA
Corresponding Author:
Zhiyuan Wang, Department of Political Science, University of Florida,
Anderson Hall 223, Gainesville, FL 32611, USA.
Email: zhiyuan.wang@ufl.edu
Choosing a Lesser Evil: Partisanship,
Labor, and Corporate Taxation under
Globalization
Zhiyuan Wang1
Abstract
Leftist governments tend to tax corporations heavily. However, they are unable to do so all the time. In this study, I
posit that whether leftist governments can enact this preferred tax policy is conditional on the policy environment.
When leftist governments are pressured by their economic competitors to reduce labor rights protection, instead of
giving in, they choose to cut corporate tax rates, because the former is more politically harmful than the latter, and
the latter is equally effective in achieving the policy goal the former is intended to accomplish. Using novel global data
on labor rights from 1994 to 2012 and the structural equivalence technique to capture the policy pressure to restrict
labor rights, I find robust evidence for the argument. This finding suggests that facing globalized economic competition,
leftist governments make strategic compromise by adopting market-oriented policies in issue areas that deviate from
their desirable ideological positions but are less costly than simply yielding to the pressure to alter policies in those
issue areas that directly hurt their core constituencies.
Keywords
leftist governments, globalization, labor, taxation
572 Political Research Quarterly 74(3)
labor rights to maintain economic competitiveness, they
seek to spur investment by allowing investors to keep a
greater share of the return to their investment through
levying lower capital taxes, which is demonstrably
effective and less politically costly.
To operationalize the pressure facing leftist govern-
ments to restrict labor rights, I first use novel global panel
data on labor rights and the structural equivalence tech-
nique to calculate yearly labor rights policies in a state’s
capital competitors, which are identified using bilateral
foreign direct investment (FDI) stock data, a practice
widely adopted in extant literature (Baccini and Koenig-
Archibugi 2014; Cao 2010; Elkins, Guzman, and
Simmons 2006). I then construct policy pressure as the
difference between a state’s own labor rights score and its
competitors’ policy for a given year, which increases as
the competitors’ policy decreases (i.e., competitors reduc-
ing labor rights protection) when it is unable to do the
same. I find robust support for the theoretical conjecture.
Although leftist governments do levy higher taxes on cor-
porations than their partisan opponents, they can only do
so when they do not face strong pressure from their com-
petitors to restrict labor rights. As the pressure increases,
they are forced to retreat from their revealed policy posi-
tions by cutting corporate tax rates.
This study contributes to current scholarship on sev-
eral fronts. By recognizing the condition under which
leftist governments are unable to pursue their preferred
tax policies, it helps to resolve the inconsistency in
partisan taxation findings (Basinger and Hallerberg
2004; Devereux, Lockwood, and Redoano 2008;
Garrett 1998; Hays 2003; Inclan, Quinn, and Shapiro
2001; Swank and Steinmo 2002; Williams and Collins
1997). In doing so, it also reconciles two seemingly
opposing strands of literature: partisan taxation schol-
arship which postulates that an ideologically staunch
leftist government insists on taxing capital heavily
(Garrett 1998; Hays 2003; Inclan, Quinn, and Shapiro
2001; Quinn and Shapiro 1991; Swank 2002) and
investment research contending that leftist govern-
ments are less bound by their revealed ideological posi-
tions in promoting economic growth (Cioffi and Höpner
2006; Pinto 2013). Finally, it supports the latest studies
that examine how leftist governments substitute opaque
pro-businesses policies for transparent pro-welfare tax
policies (Shin 2017), by shedding light on a little noted
cross-issue policy substitution.
The remaining of the article is structured as follows:
the next section reviews the literature on partisanship and
capital taxation. This is followed by a presentation of my
theoretical argument. The specifics on data and estima-
tion strategy are then given. The findings are discussed
afterward. The conclusion summarizes the key findings
and discusses the future research direction.
Partisan Government and Corporate
Taxation
Leftist governments pursue social-economic equality
through redistribution (Bradley et al. 2003). The leftist
governments’ tax policy is therefore expected to rely more
on capital than labor income taxation. Many studies sup-
port the conjecture that leftist governments set higher cor-
porate tax rates (Garrett 1998; Inclan, Quinn, and Shapiro
2001; Kumar and Quinn 2012; Shin 2017). However,
other scholars come to different conclusions: either leftist
governments lower statutory corporate tax rates (Swank
and Steinmo 2002; Williams and Collins 1997) or parti-
sanship has no statistically significant impact on tax pol-
icy enactments (Basinger and Hallerberg 2004; Devereux,
Lockwood, and Redoano 2008). These conflicting find-
ings appear to suggest that leftist governments do not pur-
sue their preferred policy unconditionally.
However, there is little research on the conditions that
constrain leftist governments’ choice on corporate tax
rates. Plümper, Troeger, and Winn’s (2009) study is a
notable exception. They argue that a leftist government
levies higher corporate taxes when fairness constraints
facing it are high. Another exception is Shin’s (2017)
recent paper. It postulates that leftist governments can
maintain high tax rates because they relax regulations on
transfer pricing, allowing firms to transfer profits abroad
with more ease and thus reduces their tax burden. These
Figure 1. Global trends in statutory corporate tax rates and
leftist governments: 1993–2012.
Source. Data on statutory corporate tax rates are taken from KPMG
(2006, 2015) Global Tax Rate Surveys. Data on leftist government are
taken from the Database of Political Institutions (Cruz, Keefer, and
Scartascini 2016).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT