The China Growth Miracle: The Role of the Formal and the Informal Institutions

AuthorYuanhua Gao,Kenneth S. Chan,Xianxiang Xu
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12193
Date01 January 2015
Published date01 January 2015
The China Growth Miracle: The Role of
the Formal and the Informal Institutions
Kenneth S. Chan
1,2
, Xianxiang Xu
2
and Yuanhua Gao
2
1
McMaster University, Hamilton, ON, Canada and
2
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-san University,
Guangzhou, China
1. INTRODUCTION
THIS paper addresses the perplexing question raised by many scholars, on why China, in
spite of its ordinary institutions, can grow so rapidly and for so long. This ‘China Growth
Miracle’ posts a challenge to the conventional wisdom (for example, Acemoglu and Johnson,
2005; Xu and Li, 2005; Du et al., 2008; Vieira et al., 2012; Lu et al., 2013 among others) that
there is a strong causation from the quality of institution to economic growth.
Cross-country regressions on growth and institutions could not provide an answer, but
could only suggest that China may be an outlier. It is therefore tempting to conclude that
institutions may not be that important for the case of China since it is still at its transition
stage of economic development. Alternatively, Bardhan (2002) and Xu et al. (2007) suggest
that the criteria for good institutions, such as property right protection and the rule-of-law,
may only be relevant to well-functioned mature market economies. For transitional econo-
mies, where the markets are still in their embryonic form, other criteria, such as a proper bal-
ance between centralisation and decentralisation of government to promote performance,
could be more useful indicators for effective or good institutions.
In this paper, we investigate whether or not ‘good’ institutions are important for economic
growth in China. Since each region in China has different regional institutional quality and
growth rates, we will look into provincial and city-level data for answers. We will use multi-
ple measures of government efficiency to gauze the regional government efficiency, and a
new set of instrumental variables.
Other than the formal institutions, the informal institution usually plays a significant role in
governance in the developing countries. A formal institution governs through a well-structured
organisation and is usually rule-based. An informal institution governs through relations/net-
work and reciprocity within the community, based on shared social values and norms (Wil-
liamson, 2000).
1
While the formal institution governs by direct coercion through the state
mechanism, the informal institution governs by consensual control and voluntary compliance
in the community. Williamson (2000) thinks that the informal institution is a more important
institution than the formal institution as the former constraints the action of the latter and that
We are indebted to two anonymous referees, Eden Yu, Vinh Dang, Yi Lu, Pinghan Liang and seminar
participants at CCER, Peking University, National Taiwan University and Guangdong University of For-
eign Studies for helpful comments of earlier drafts. Xianxiang Xu gratefully acknowledges the financial
support from national natural science foundation of China (No.71373290).
1
Some authors prefer to use the term social capital rather than the informal institution (see Nannicini
et al., 2010; Gorodnichenko and Roland, 2011). The definition of social capital, norms, cultural values
and the informal institution are not completely identical in spite of huge overlaps. A distinction between
these concepts is beyond the scope of this paper. But for convenience, we will use the term informal
institution here to include all of these concepts.
©2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 63
The World Economy (2015)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12193
The World Economy
it takes longer to change than the latter. Historically, China’s informal institution, based on
the Confucian communitarian ethos, was vital in governing China because of its huge land
mass and population which raised the monitoring cost of the central government. The social
values in China stress communitarian ethics rather than individualism. These social values
proved to be a useful mechanism to maintain law and order and effective governance in rural
or distant areas. Authority from the central government was supplemented by those from the
local elites/gentries, who had relied on the local social network and communitarian ethics of
the local population to govern. Hence, the informal institution improved the effectiveness of
the formal institution. China was governed quite successfully by this mixture of formal and
informal institutions for more than two thousand years.
By looking back into Chinese history, we see that the quality of the informal institution
must have played an important role in the governance of the Chinese society. Although the
informal institution persists for a very long period of time (Williamson, 2000), it is hard to
judge how much of the informal institution today come from China’s past. Nonetheless even
today, transactions in the Chinese economy rely more heavily on ‘guanxi’, a network of infor-
mal arrangements, than on the formal contracts (Su and Fung, 2013). To find out the recent
impact of the informal institution, we need to find a good measurement for the informal insti-
tution, an issue the present paper will address.
This paper finds that it is the strength of the informal institution which has aided China’s
growth and development over the last four decades in spite of its mediocre formal institution.
There are clearly mutual interactions between the formal and the informal institutions in
China (see Helmke and Levitsky, 2004). The treatment of these interactions will be discussed
in subsection 3bAre the formal and the informal institutions substitute or complement for
each other? Would the presence of the formal institution ‘crowd-out’ the informal institution?
In this paper, we find some evidence from the Chinese regional data that the formal and the
informal institutions are close complements.
A caveat in this paper is the weak theoretical relationship between institutions and growth .
As pointed out by Acemoglu and Robinson (2010), we only have a very preliminary under-
standing of the relationship between political power, institutions and economic performance.
We still do not know exactly why some dictatorships, such as those in Asia, are developmen-
tal, while others dictatorships, such as those in Africa and Latin America, are not. While the
theoretical literature may have produced ambiguous predictions, the empirical literature may
be able to offer some insightful empirical regularity. In a recent review of the empirical work
on institution and long-run growth, Vieira et al. (2012) concluded that, overall, the quality of
institutions matters in predicting long-run growth in cross-country studies. Our paper follows
this fruitful line of empirical investigation and tests the important contribution from China’s
informal institution, in addition to its formal institution.
2
The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 lays down the theoretical
framework and predictions from the conventional growth model for empirical study. Section 3
tests of the predictions, using provincial and city-level data. New instrumental variables are
introduced in the 2SLS regressions. Section 4 extends part of the framework to panel regres-
2
Vieira et al. (2012) also review the empirical work by Glaeser et al. (2004) who are critical of the
institutional approach. They find that human capital (initial level of education) is more important for
growth than institutions. Perhaps, the significance of the human capital in their regressions is picking up
the impact from the informal institution or from the social capital, on which education has a deep
influence.
©2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
64 K. S. CHAN, X. XU AND Y. GAO

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT