Chapter II. Development of the Doctrine

Pages5-34
5
CHAPTER II
DEVELOPMENT OF THE DOCTRINE
The state action doctrine has grown from a relatively minor part of a
1943 Supreme Court decision into an important antitrust exemption and a
significant component of recent jurisprudence regarding the appropriate
balance of power between both state and national governments and the
judicial and legislative branches. Much of that development took place
in a series of Supreme Court decisions between 1975 and 1992. This
chapter examines the history of the doctrine through the decisions that
were most important to its development.
A. The Doctrine’s Origin
1. Introduction in Parker v. Brown (1943)1
In 1933, the California legislature enacted the Agricultural Prorate
Act to authorize the establishment of programs for the marketing of the
state’s agricultural goods “so as to restrict competition among the
growers and maintain prices in the distribution of their commodities to
packers.”2 The act established a process by which commodity-specific
program committees would be formed with a majority membership of
persons nominated by producers of the commodity. This committee, in
turn, would establish a so-called proration marketing program, which, if
1. 317 U.S. 341 (1943). As Justice Stewart explained in his dissent in Cantor
v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.S. 579, 615 n.3 (1976) (Cantor), the
progenitor of the state action doctrine was Olsen v. Smith, 195 U.S. 332
(1904), a decision—upholding a Texas statute fixing rates charged by pilots
operating in the Port of Galveston—relied on by th e Parker Court for the
proposition that when a state, acting as sovereign, imposes a restraint on
commerce, such restraint does not violate the Sherman Act. See Parker,
317 U.S. at 352.
2. 317 U.S. at 346.
6 State Action Practice Manual
ratified by a supermajority of the producers, would be enforceable by
criminal (misdemeanor) and civil liability sanctions.
The proration marketing program at issue in Parker required that
raisin producers’ marketing efforts for the 1940 raisin crop be subject to
a variety of restrictions. Porter L. Brown was engaged in producing,
purchasing, and packing raisins for interstate sale and shipment. He
challenged the validity of the raisin program as a violation of the
Commerce Clause and the Sherman Act.3 After a three-judge district
court panel permanently enjoined the program,4 the Supreme Court
granted review.5
The Supreme Court reversed the injunction, finding that the raisin
marketing program was not rendered invalid by the Sherman Act,6 the
Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937,7 or the Commerce
Clause of the U.S. Constitution.8 In its abbreviated discussion of the
Sherman Act,9 the unanimous Court found “nothing in the language of
the Sherman Act or in its history which suggests that its purpose was to
restrain a state or its officers or agents from activities directed by its
legislature.”10 Because “an unexpressed purpose to nullify a state’s
control over its officers and agents is not lightly to be attributed to
3. Id. at 346-50.
4. Brown v. Parker, 39 F. Supp. 895, 902 (S.D. Cal. 1941).
5. 317 U.S. at 345. Petitioner W.B. Parker was the California Director of
Agriculture, a state official integral to the working of the Agricultural
Prorate Act.
6. Id. at 352.
7. Id. at 358. The opinion assumed “that a stabilization program adopted
under the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act would supersede the state
act,” but noted that the federal Secretary of Agriculture had “not proposed
or promulgated any order regulating raisins.” Id. at 353. The Court
concluded: “We find no conflict between the two acts and no such
occupation of the legislative field by the mere adoption of the Agricultural
Marketing Agreement Act, without the issuance of any order by the
Secretary putting it into effect, as would preclude the effective operation of
the state act.” Id. at 358.
8. Id. at 368 (“[W]hatever effect the operation of the California program may
have on interstate commerce, it is one which it has been the policy of
Congress to aid and encourage . . . . Nor is the effect on the commerce
greater than or substantially different in kind from that contemplated by the
stabilization programs authorized by federal statutes.”).
9. See id. at 350-52.
10. Id. at 350-51.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT