The Changing Relationship between Banking Crises and Capital Inflows

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12242
Published date01 May 2016
AuthorJason Rastovski
Date01 May 2016
The Changing Relationship between Banking Crises
and Capital Inflows
Jason Rastovski*
Abstract
Different types of capital inflows have varied effects when predicting banking crises in emerging and
developing economies, and these relationships have meaningfully changed over time. In a sample of 29
developing and emerging economies over the period 19761991 increases in short-term debt inflows raised
the probability of a banking crisis while increases in inflows for long-term borrowing by the private sector
had the opposite effect. Conversely, over the period 19922007 increases in inflows for long-term borrowing
by the private sector and for equity investment both increased the probability of a banking crisis. The
findings suggest distinct optimal capital account liberalization policies between the two periods.
1. Introduction
Since the early 1970s banking crises in developing and emerging economies have
become more frequent and capital inflows have increased considerably. The
literature has found that increases in total capital inflows generally precede banking
crises. In this paper we regress a binary variable indicating the onset of a banking
crisis on different types of lagged capital inflows. In a sample of 29 countries over
19762007 the probability of a country experiencing the onset of a banking crisis in
any given year was 5.9%. Over this time period it is not clear whether or not the
types of capital inflows a country experiences matters in predicting banking crises;
however, splitting the sample into two equal periods shows that the type of inflow
does matter and that the relationship between inflows and banking crises has
changed over time.
From 19761991 to 19922007 the probability of the outbreak of a banking crisis
in a given country increased from 5.4% to 6.5%. During 19761991 a 5 percentage
point increase in the lagged 5-year growth rate of short-term external debt
(borrowed by the public and private sectors combined) increased the probability of
a banking crisis by 3.1 percentage points, whereas a 5 percentage point increase in
the lagged 5-year growth rate of long-term external borrowing by the private sector
decreased the probability of a banking crisis by 2.2 percentage points. Other types
of capital inflows are not statistically significant predictors in the most complete
regression specification. During the 19922007 period increases in the growth rates
of long-term external borrowing by the private sector and foreign equity investment
(portfolio and direct investment combined) are statistically significant in predicting
banking crises. In this period a 5 percentage point increase in the lagged 5-year
growth rate of long-term external borrowing by the private sector increased the
probability of a banking crisis by 1.1 percentage points, and a 5 percentage point
increase in the lagged 5-year growth rate of foreign equity investment increased
*Rastovski (Corresponding author): Centre College, Danville, KY, 40422, USA. Tel: +1-859-238-6504;
E-mail: jason.rastovski@centre.edu.
Review of Development Economics, 20(2), 514–530, 2016
DOI:10.1111/rode.12242
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
that probability by 2.0 percentage points. Given the high volatility of the growth
rates of these types of external liabilities
1
and the observed frequency of banking
crises these effects are economically large.
This paper contributes to the literature on banking crises, financial openness, and
the differentiation between gross and net capital flows by: being the first to tie
equity and capital inflows owing to short-term debt and different types of long-term
debt to banking crises in a way that their relative impact can be observed;
2
using a
de facto measure of financial openness in the volume of capital inflows (following
Kose et al., 2009; Lane and Milesi-Ferretti, 2007) when assessing the impact of
inflows on banking crises; emphasizing the role gross rather than net capital flows in
crisis analysis (following Obstfeld, 2010; Lane, 2000; Mendoza and Terrones, 2008;
Forbes and Warnock, 2011).
Because banking crises can be disruptive and expensive to remediate,
understanding their causes has meaningful policy and welfare implications.
Eichengreen and Rose (1998) cite the cost of resolving financial crises and
recapitalizing banking systems at 10% of gross domestic product (GDP) in Malaysia
(19851988), 15% of GDP in Mexico (19941997), 20% of GDP in Venezuela (1994
1997), 30% of GDP in Chile (19811986) and 50% of GDP in Kuwait (19901991).
Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) find that banking crises typically lead to sharp declines in
tax revenues and significant increases in government expenditures, and that on
average government debt rises by 86% in the 3 years after a banking crisis. Given that
a banking crisis is frequently resolved by government nationalization of banks this
increase in sovereign borrowing is not unexpected. They also find that banking crises
tend to be much shorter in duration than sovereign debt defaults, presumably because
of it being more costly to incur the negative effects on trade and investment (from a
banking crisis) than for the government to avoid international creditors (following a
default). In addition to showing the importance of studying banking crises, another
strand of the literature ties banking crises to capital inflows.
Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) find that financial liberalization often precedes
banking crises. In 18 of the 26 banking crises they study, the financial sector had
been liberalized within the preceding 5 years. They use a mixture of developing and
developed countries, but Eichengreen and Arteta (2002) point out that the
characteristics of banking crises in developing and emerging economies are distinct
from those in developed economies. They indicate that banks account for a larger
share of financial institutions in developing countries, that those banks’ liabilities
tend to have shorter maturities, they have less developed supervision and
regulation, and they have less ability to hedge external risks than their counterparts
in developed countries. For these reasons our analysis focuses on developing and
emerging economies. The second key difference between this paper and Kaminsky
and Reinhart (1999) is that they consider the effect of general domestic financial
liberalization (captured using the M2 multiplier, domestic credit to GDP, the real
interest rate and the lendingdeposit rate ratio) on banking crises, where we
specifically look at de facto financial openness. The de jure financial openness index
constructed in Chinn and Ito (2008) could also be used to conduct analysis similar
to Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999). This index quantifies formal policy restrictions
on a country’s interactions with the rest of the world.
3
In this paper the focus is on
identifying the impact of changes in types of capital inflows, which may not be
captured by the de jure measure of capital account openness used as a component
of the Chin and Ito index. Others have analyzed the impact of capital inflows on
banking crises, but restrict their analyses to only consider inflow “bonanzas.”
BANKING CRISES AND CAPITAL INFLOWS 515
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT