Changing Prices in a Changing Climate: Electoral Competition and Fossil Fuel Taxation

Published date01 July 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221141853
AuthorJared J. Finnegan
Date01 July 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2023, Vol. 56(8) 12571290
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140221141853
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Changing Prices in a
Changing Climate:
Electoral Competition
and Fossil Fuel Taxation
Jared J. Finnegan
1
Abstract
When do governments adopt ambitious climate policy? Charting the theo-
retical territory between climate change politics and long-term policymaking,
this paper highlights the role of electoral competition in shaping how poli-
ticians respond to the intertemporal tradeoff of one important climate change
mitigation policy: fossil fuel taxation. The more secure the government is in
off‌ice, the more insulated it is from the vagaries of political competition, and
the more likely it is to impose costs on constituents today to generate a future
stable climate. By inf‌luencing governmentstime preferences, competition
structures the myopia of elected off‌icials. I test the arguments using an original
dataset of gasoline taxation across high-income democracies between 1988
and 2013. I f‌ind evidence that higher levels of electoral competition are
associated with lower gasoline tax rates, and that the relationship is mod-
erated by the level of costs imposed on voters, but not government parti-
sanship. More generally, the analysis highlights when governments can
increase consumer prices to address long-term challenges.
Keywords
climate change, fossil fuel taxation, long-term policymaking, electoral
competition, policy myopia
1
Department of Political Science, University College London, London, UK
Corresponding Author:
Jared J. Finnegan, Department of Political Science, University College London, 29-30 Tavistock
Square, London WC1H 9QU, UK.
Email: j.f‌innegan@ucl.ac.uk
Introduction
Climate change is one of the most signif‌icant long-term policy challenges
facing governments. To address it, economists have, for decades, advocated
carbon pricing (Nordhaus, 1977). Increasing the price of fossil fuels should
reduce their consumption and attendant carbon dioxide (CO
2
) emissions.
However, despite its theoretical elegance and wide diffusion in climate policy
discourse (Meckling & Allan, 2020), politicians have been slow to take up
such advice. By some estimates, 85% of global greenhouse gas emissions
remain unpriced (High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices, 2017) and only
around a quarter of emissions from OECD and G20 countries are priced at or
above 30 per tonnethe lower-end estimate needed to meet the objectives of
the Paris Agreement (OECD, 2021).
One explanation for this lack of enthusiasm is that vote-seeking politicians
are reticent about drawing the ire of voters who prefer low energy prices
(Rabe, 2010,2018). Indeed, a large body of survey research consistently f‌inds
that individuals dislike costly climate policies (e.g., Drews & Bergh, 2015;
Jagers and Hammar, 2009;Shwom et al., 2010). Beyond the ballot box,
governments are fearful of mass protest in response to tax rate hikes, such as
recent ones by the gilets jaunes in France.
The political calculus of imposing costs may be improved if the associated
benef‌its arrive quickly to voters; since voters and politicians tend to be
impatient, preferring policy benef‌its that arrive earlier in time (Jacobs and
Matthews, 2012;Sheffer et al., 2017). However, the primary benef‌it of carbon
pricinga stable climateis a diffuse, global public good generated over
decades. Further complicating matters, avoided climate change is the absence
of future harm, rather than an increase in an easily understood and tangible
consumption good, such as healthcare, infrastructure, pensions, or education.
Even ancillary benef‌its of climate mitigation, such as green jobs, innovation,
or reduced air pollution, are likely to only be manifest in the medium term. In
this way, fossil fuel taxation constitutes a type of intertemporal redis-
tributionshort-term costs are borne today for benef‌its that arrive in the future
(Finnegan, 2022a;Jacobs, 2011).
Considering these impediments, we can see why the politics of carbon
pricing have proven tumultuous. Indeed, a perennial critique of democratic
politics is that, being motivated primarily by re-election, politicians are
systematically unable to see beyond the next contest. Instead of making tough
choices today, they appeal to votersshort-sightedness, put off any sacrif‌ice for
as long as possible, and ignore the future consequences. Yet, while the myopic
pressures of democratic politics are daunting, the actual record of fossil fuel
taxation presents a more complicated story.
As I show in this paper, fossil fuel tax rates vary widely across the high-
income democracies and within them over time. In some countries, such as the
1258 Comparative Political Studies 56(8)
Netherlands and Belgium, tax rates increase almost every year while rates
have remained virtually unchanged for decades in the US and Canada. What
explains this variation? Why are some governments willing to invest in long-
term climate policies, like fossil fuel taxes, even at the risk of imposing short-
term costs on their constituents? Surprisingly, we still do not know much
about the answers to these questions. Despite its self-evident importance and
the centrality of politics, climate change has remained curiously absent as a
mainstream concern for political science (Keohane, 2015).
This article investigates the reasons for the puzzling variation in fossil fuel tax
rates by charting the largely unexplored theoretical territory between compar-
ative climate change politics and research from political science and economics
on long-termpolicymaking.It focuses on the roleof the electoral environment in
structuring politicianstime preferences. The basic argument is that the more
secure the government is in off‌ice, the more insulated it is from the vagaries of
political competition, and therefore, the more likely it is to increase taxes. By
shaping the incentives of elected off‌icials to impose direct and highly visible
costs on voters today, electoral competition informs how governments come to
value the future benef‌its of climate mitigation. In this way, electoral competition
shapes politiciansdiscount rates, and by extension theirpolicy myopia. WhileI
focus on fuel taxes, the argument is applicable more broadly to any long-term
policy problem that requires short-term increases in consumer prices.
To test the theory, I analyze taxation of an important and widely consumed
fossil fuel: gasoline. Gasoline is one of the largest sources of carbon pollution
worldwide. In the US, for example, it accounted for 22% of energy-related
CO
2
emissions in 2018; on par with coal (U.S. Energy Information
Administration, 2020). For this reason, gasoline taxes have been high-
lighted as one of the most important fossil fuel taxes adopted to date (Sterner,
2007); yet, pricing policies around the world have been mixed (Ross et al.,
2017).
Utilizing an original dataset of gasoline excise tax rates and a measure of
electoral competition developed using loss probability data from Kayser and
Lindst¨
adt (2015), I examine the relationship between competition and
taxation within twenty high-income democracies between 1988 and 2013
using f‌ixed effects models. I f‌ind robust evidence that higher levels of
electoral competition are associated with lower gasoline tax rates, even after
controlling for a wide range of potential confounders. Furthermore, the
negative inf‌luence of competition is moderated by politiciansperceptions of
voter preferences. When a tax increase is expected to impose high costs on
their constituents, because gasoline consumption is widespread, politicians
are even less likely to increase rates. Perhaps surprisingly, I f‌ind that
government partisanship plays little role in shaping tax rates. Takentogether,
the results provide strong evidence that electoral competition structures
Finnegan 1259

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT