CEO age and tax planning

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/rfe.1072
Published date01 April 2020
AuthorHui Liang James
Date01 April 2020
Rev Financ Econ. 2020;38:275–299. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rfe
|
275
© 2019 University of New Orleans
1
|
INTRODUCTION
This study examines the association between CEO age and corporate tax planning. Tax planning refers to activities of restruc-
turing transactions to increase after‐tax income and/or after‐tax cash flows. As such activities involve significant uncertainty,
tax planning is often viewed as a long‐term investment (Minnick & Noga, 2010). When carried out effectively, tax planning
leads to reduced taxes and increased shareholder’s wealth (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010; Robinson, Sikes, & Weaver, 2010).
However, aggressive tax planning may subject firms to additional taxes, penalties, and unfavorable public scrutiny (Hanlon &
Slemrod, 2009).
CEOs play an important role in shaping firms’ tax policies by setting general directions of firms’ tax strategies (Dyreng,
Hanlon, & Maydew, 2010). CEOs have incentives to minimize tax payments when their compensations are directly linked
to accounting‐based performance (Phillips, 2003) and/or when they are offered with stock‐based compensation contracts
(Armstrong, Blouin, Jagolinzer, & Larcker, 2015; Rego & Wilson, 2012). Campbell, Guan, and Li (2018) document a positive
relation between CEO severance pay and corporate tax planning, suggesting CEO severance pay induces risk‐averse managers
to engage in more tax planning by providing contractual protection against their career concerns.1
Existing studies provide evidence showing that CEO age affects various corporate policies. Younger CEOs have greater
incentives to favorably influence the labor market perception of their quality in order to obtain higher compensation and job
security (Gibbons & Murphy, 1992; Holmstrom, 1999; Prendergast & Stole, 1996). As such, younger CEOs are more likely to
adopt risky investment and financial policies (Croci, Giudice, & Jankensgård, 2017; Li, Low, & Makhija, 2017; Serfling, 2014).
Conversely, older executives enjoy their “quite life” and prefer less risky investments (Bertrand & Schoar, 2003). Furthermore,
older CEOs are less efficient in complex cognition, new information processing, and problem‐solving (Haug & Eggers, 1991;
Mata, Schooler, & Rieskamp, 2007; Raz et al., 2004; Resnick, Pham, Kraut, Zonderman, & Davatzikos, 2003; Schaie, 1996).
Hence, the ability to engage in actions to effectively lower tax burden is expected to be impaired by age. Lastly, older individuals
Received: 27 February 2019
|
Revised: 15 June 2019
|
Accepted: 19 June 2019
DOI: 10.1002/rfe.1072
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
CEO age and tax planning
Hui LiangJames
Accounting, Finance & Business Law,
Soules College of Business,University of
Texas at Tyler, Tyler, Texas
Correspondence
Hui Liang James, Accounting, Finance &
Business Law, Soules College of Business,
University of Texas at Tyler, SCOB 350.06,
3900 University Blvd, Tyler, TX 75799,
USA.
Email: hjames@uttyler.edu
Abstract
This study investigates the association between CEO age and corporate tax planning.
Using a sample of 11,537 firm‐year observations from the fiscal year 1997–2013,
I find CEO age exerts an economically significant influence on firms’ tax policies,
incremental to economic determinants identified in prior research. Specifically, CEO
age is positively related to cash and GAAP effectivetax rates, and negatively related
to permanent book‐tax difference, suggesting that older CEOs are less likely to take
actions to lower tax burden. The results hold across different model specifications
and robustness tests to address potential bias arising from endogeneity, sample selec-
tion issue, and the confounding effect of CEO tenure.
KEYWORDS
CEO age, ethics, risk‐taking incentives, tax planning
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G30; H26; G40
276
|
JAMES
are exposed to traditional culture for a prolonged time and more likely to draw inferences consistent with ethical behavior
(Dawson, 1997; Deshpande, 1997; Mudrack, 1989; Peterson, Rhoads, & Vaught, 2001; Terpstra, Rozell, & Robinson, 1993;
Twenge & Campbell, 2008). As paying a fair amount of taxes is generally viewed as socially responsible (Freedman, 2003;
Landolf, 2006; Williams, 2007), older CEOs should be less likely to engage in tax planning.
This study investigates the influence of CEO age on corporate tax planning using a sample of 11,537 firm‐year observations
from the fiscal year 1997–2013. GAAP and Cash effective tax rates are employed to capture the cross‐sectional variation in
firms’ total tax planning (Armstrong et al., 2015; Campbell et al., 2018; Dyreng, Hanlon, & Maydew, 2008; Robinson et al.,
2010). To overcome the measurement issue in annual effective tax rates (ETRs) as indicated in Dyreng et al. (2008), I use the
3‐year average GAAP ETR (GAAP_ETR) and 3‐year average Cash ETR (CashETR). Following Armstrong et al. (2015) and
Balakrishnan, Blouin, and Guay (2012), I benchmark a given firm’s ETRs relative to similar firms with the difference in the av-
erage GAAP_ETR/CashETR between the firm’s size and industry peers and the given firm (D_GAAP_ETR/D_CashETR). The
last proxy for tax planning is permanent book‐tax differences (PBTD) (Frank, Lynch, & Rego, 2009; Goh, Lee, Lim, & Shevlin,
2016). Firms engaging in higher levels of tax planning are expected to be associated with lower tax rates, higher differences in
tax rates between industry peers and the sample firms, and higher permanent book‐tax differences.
The results show that CEO age is positively related to tax rates and negatively related to PBTD, suggesting that younger CEOs
are more likely to undertake tax policies to minimize taxes. Other things equal, firms with CEOs under 50years of age are associated
with 0.96 percentage point reduction in CashETR, 1.14 percentage point reduction in GAAP_ETR, 1.07 percentage point increase in
D_CashETR, 1 percentage point increase in D_GAAP_ETR, and 0.57 percentage point increase in PBTD, compared to firms with
CEOs over 60years of age. Moreover, firms headed by CEOs with age between 50 and 59 are associated with 0.71 percentage point
reduction in CashETR, 1.03 percentage point reduction in GAAP_ETR, 0.69 percentage point increase in D_CashETR, 0.94 percent-
age point increase in D_GAAP_ETR, and 0.42 percentage point increase in PBTD, compared to firms with CEOs over 60years of age.
Dyreng et al. (2010) find that the age of executives does not explain much of the variation in tax avoidance. However, their
sample selection and estimation method are different from this study. Following Bertrand and Schoar (2003), Dyreng et al.
(2010) estimate executives’ fixed effect on tax policies using a sample of 908 executives who were employed by more than
one firm in order to isolate the executive effect from the firm effect. As shown in Graham, Li, and Qiu (2012), the sample cre-
ated through this method is “necessarily small due to the relatively small number of executive job changes in most samples.”
Moreover, Graham et al. (2012) argue that managers who never change firms may be significantly different from those who
have moved. Hence, this sample selection process might result in sample selection bias, which could mean that the results are
not indicative of the true relation. Second, the different results may be attributable to different sample periods. The sample in
Dyreng et al. (2010) is from 1992 to 2006, but the sample in this study is from 1997 to 2013. In summary, Dyreng et al. (2010)
identifies, for managers who change jobs, a manager fixed effect associated with corporate tax planning, but the study does not
find that age is significantly associated with this manager fixed effect. In contrast, I find that for a relatively broad sample of
CEOs (not limited to managers who change firms during my study), age is consistently associated with corporate tax planning.
I conduct a variety of tests to mitigate various econometric concerns. First, the observed association between CEO age and tax
planning could arise from the systematic difference between firms led by older CEOs and firms led by younger CEOs. Second, CEO
age and tax planning may be endogenously determined by variables omitted from the model. For example, firms may hire younger
CEOs because they favor lower taxable income; thus, the relation between CEO age and tax planning is due to omitted firm fixed
effect. In both scenarios, the endogeneity between CEO age and tax planning violates the conditions of OLS regressions, leading
to inconsistent and biased coefficient estimates. I employ three identification strategies to alleviate the concern of spurious relation.
First, I apply propensity score matching to identify control firms with older CEOs but are otherwise indistinguishable from firms with
younger CEOs, and repeat the analysis with this matched sample. This method isolates a control sample of firms headed by older
CEOs from a treated sample of firms headed by younger CEOs in a way that the control sample exhibits no observable difference
from the treated sample. Second, I use an instrumental variable to create a source of exogenous variation in CEO age. Following
Serfling (2014), Cline and Yore (2016), and Croci et al. (2017), I instrument CEO age with the level of the Consumer Price Index
(CPI) in a CEO’s birth year. The rationale is that older CEOs are likely to be born in early years with lower CPI. Thus, CEO age and
CPI in the birth year should be significantly and negatively correlated, satisfying relevance restriction. Little evidence, if any, implies
CPI in CEO birth year is related to current tax planning practice adopted by the firm headed by this CEO, satisfying exclusion re-
striction. Lastly, I adopt the firm fixed effect regression to mitigate the bias arising from the time‐invariant fixed effect. Potential time
effect on the tax planning incentives is controlled by year indicator variables. The results consistently indicate that firms with younger
CEOs are associated with significantly lower tax rates and higher permanent book‐tax differences, confirming the baseline results.
Younger CEOs are more likely to be CEOs with shorter service. It is arguably possible that the finding of younger CEOs
are associated with high levels of tax planning is due to the new CEO effect: newly hired CEOs have greater incentives engage
in tax planning to increase compensation and job security. In addition, CEOs near retirement age may be more conservative in

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT