Capital market integration and gender inequality

Published date01 August 2019
Date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12593
AuthorMizuki Komura,Hikaru Ogawa
Rev Dev Econ. 2019;23:1387–1413. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode
|
1387
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Globalization affects gender empowerment and fertility outcomes all over the world through many
labor-market-related factors. The emergence of a new globalized labor market directly changes the
working styles of mothers and fathers as well as their fertility decisions (Rees & Riezman, 2012).
Social remittances by immigrants to their home countries are also a direct effect of the integration
of the labor market attributed to globalization. For example, if the women are relatively empowered
and family size is relatively small in the destination country, the immigrants may bring its culture or
social norms back to their home countries, and spread them in the communities there (Fargues, 2011;
Beine, Docquier, & Schiff, 2013, Ferrant & Tuccio, 2015, and Bertoli & Marchetta, 2015). Moreover,
globalization characterized by market integration in production factors and final goods also causes
indirect effects. For instance, the capital inflow accompanied by capital market openings will benefit
workers who are complementary to capital in production, while it may harm workers who have a less
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12593
REGULAR ARTICLE
Capital market integration and gender inequality
MizukiKomura1
|
HikaruOgawa2
1Faculty of Economics,Musashi University
and IZA, Tokyo, Japan
2Graduate School of Economics
and Graduate School of Public
Policy,University of Tokyo, Tokyo, Japan
Correspondence
Hikaru Ogawa, Graduate School of
Economics and Graduate School of Public
Policy, University of Tokyo, 7-3-1 Hongo
Bunkyo, Tokyo, 113-0033, Japan.
Email: ogawa@e.u-tokyo.ac.jp
Abstract
This study explores the effects of globalization on gender
inequality. Specifically, we describe how, in terms of capi-
tal market integration, globalization alters the gender gap in
wage rates through changes in labor demand for capital-in-
tensive sectors. Consequently, via changes in the bargaining
positions of men and women, globalization leads to oppo-
site effects on the couple's labor supply and fertility deci-
sions in capital-importing and capital-exporting countries.
Moreover, by considering the properties of the industrial
structures of capital-importing and capital-exporting coun-
tries, we show that globalization induces empirically
observed declines in fertility rates throughout the world.
KEYWORDS
capital market integration, bargaining power, gender inequality
1388
|
Komura and ogawa
complementary relationship with capital by widening the wage gap with the former. If either female
or male workers tend to be complementary to capital in production, the capital flows affect outcomes
such as the wages and employment of men and women in the labor market, leading to changes in gen-
der relationships and household decisions.
Since the influential work by Galor and Weil (1996), many studies have explored the role of capi-
tal accumulation in gender empowerment and household production, focusing on fertility decisions.1
These studies consider the situation in which men and women are affected asymmetrically by capital
accumulation in the process of economic development. If we assume an economy where female labor
is relatively complementary to capital, capital accumulation leads to a relatively higher female wage.
This results in a higher opportunity cost of having children, followed by a decline in fertility.
Analyzing an increase in the level of capital from the viewpoint of an economy composed
of multiple countries, rather than of one country, allows us to shed new light on the relationship be-
tween change in capital stock and gender empowerment. The total capital in the world for a certain
period is fixed, implying that an increase in the capital of one country is possible only when the capital
elsewhere, that is, the rest of the world, is reduced. As such, the effects become more complicated. If
a country experiencing capital inflow enjoys higher female wage and lower fertility rate, the country
with capital outflow may experience the opposite: the capital outflow causes the drop in female wage
rates, leading to a rise in fertility rate. In this case, the effects of changes in the level of capital in each
country as well as the economy as a whole are not easy to determine. This study tries to answer this
question by exploring the effects of changes in capital levels on the said aspects.
For our purposes, we develop a model with three distinct features. First, to examine capital mo-
bility, we utilize a model of capital tax competition originally presented by Zodrow and Mieszkowski
(1986) and Wilson (1986). The model analyzes the effects of market integration of an economy con-
sisting of multiple countries (e.g. EU integration). It succeeded in analyzing the impacts of global-
ization on each country. The theory predicts that globalization, in terms of capital market integration,
allows countries with higher returns from investment to attract capital from all over the world, result-
ing in asymmetric effects on individuals with heterogeneities such as the level of skills, employment
status, and capital endowments (Gerber & Hewitt, 1987; Lai, 2010; Ogawa, Sato, & Tamai, 2016).
However, these studies define workers and households only as rational “individuals”, and they are
often assumed to be homogenous within the household.
Second, we refer to heterogeneity among workers: male and female workers constitute different
production labor inputs in accordance with the degree of complementarity to capital. Galor and Weil
(1996), Abio, Mahieu, and Patxot (2004), and Sauré and Zoabi (2009), among others, assumed that
women are complementary to physical capital. However, the degree of complementarity of workers
and the main industry of the country vary, especially in accordance with the degree of economic de-
velopment. So far, the manufacturing and services sectors represent the main industries in developed
countries, while developing countries are more likely to rely on manufacturing and agriculture rather
than the service industry. Moreover, a large portion of female employment in developing countries
is combined with machines owing to the automation of production processes and lower wages for
women than for men (Juhn, Ujhelyi, & Villegas-Sanchez, 2014), while in developed countries women
tend to engage in the service sector and men are the main workers in the manufacturing industries.2
Thus, new factories built using mobile capital do not necessarily create employment for workers of
a specific gender. Therefore, it is worth investigating this issue without characterizing both countries
with the same production technology.
The growing literature on globalization and women's empowerment continues to study this issue,
but the results as to which gender is complementary to physical capital seem inconclusive. For exam-
ple, opposing the view that female labor alone is likely to be affected by globalization, Fontana and

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT