Capacity‐constrained entrepreneurs and their product portfolio size: The response to a platform design change on a Chinese sharing economy platform

AuthorXueming Luo,Zhijie Lin,C. Jennifer Tae
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/sej.1360
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Capacity-constrained entrepreneurs and their
product portfolio size: The response to a platform
design change on a Chinese sharing economy
platform
C. Jennifer Tae
1
| Xueming Luo
1
| Zhijie Lin
2
1
Fox School of Business, Temple University, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
2
School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China
Correspondence
Zhijie Lin, School of Economics and
Management, Tsinghua University,
440 Weilun Building, Beijing 100084, China.
Email: dr.zhijie.lin@gmail.com
Abstract
Research summary: How do entrepreneurs on a sharing
economy platform (SEP) with a limit to aggregate output
(capacity constraints) respond to a platform design change
emphasizing buyer feedback? Not all supply-side com-
plementors can diversify or scale their offerings. Focusing
on those who can change the former, but not the latter, we
examine how entrepreneurs change their product portfolio
size after the platform design changed to emphasize buyer
feedback. We found that their product portfolio size
decreased following the change, and more so for those with
more positive feedback. While the sales increased for entre-
preneurs after the change, buyer feedback deteriorated.
Our results show how SEPs in emerging economies can fos-
ter entrepreneurship and elucidate the importance of
nonscale-free resources of supply-side entrepreneurs to
better understand platform dynamics.
Managerial summary: Do sellers change the number of
products on offer when the app owner rewards sellers with
high user ratings? While research has examined how sellers
adjust the number of products to get high ratings, little
attention has been paid to sellers with capacity constraints.
Received: 15 February 2019 Revised: 3 May 2020 Accepted: 11 May 2020 Published on: 11 August 2020
DOI: 10.1002/sej.1360
© 2020 Strategic Management Society
302 Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal. 2020;14:302328.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/sej
This is problematic, as sellers on sharing economy apps
often have a limit on the total quantity of products they can
produce. Using data from a Chinese home cooked meal sell-
ing app, we show that sellers decreased the number of
products they sell when the app owner began to reward
high user ratings. The decrease was more pronounced for
sellers with higher ratings. As a result, sales revenue
increased, but user ratings decreased. Implications for prac-
titioners and policymakers are discussed within.
KEYWORDS
microentrepreneurship, nonscale-free resources, platform design,
product portfolio size, sharing economy platform ecosystems
1|INTRODUCTION
The growth of the sharing economy (gig economy, on-demand economy, or peer-to-peer business), exemplified by
Uber and Airbnb, has been enabled by platform settings that facilitate interactions between supply-side com-
plementors and demand-side users (Cennamo & Santalo, 2013; Rietveld & Eggers, 2018; Zhu & Iansiti, 2012). Such
platforms make it easy for participants on the supply side to leverage existing, underutilized assets they already own
to serve a massive potential customer base who wants products and services offered through such assets on demand
(Sundararajan, 2016; Zervas, Proserpio, & Byers, 2017). Although sharing economy platforms are ubiquitous around
the world, their growth and importance have been pronounced in emerging economies; manifest in the fact that Asia
accounts for more than 70% of the ride-hailing market in the world
1
and that China's sharing economy, which
recorded trading volume of RMB 294.2 billion (approximately US$41.7 billion) in 2018, is projected to grow more
than 30% per annum year-on-year until 2022.
2
Two characteristics set supply-side participants on sharing economy platforms apart from those on other plat-
forms. First, participants on sharing economy platforms work whenever and wherever they want in response to exis-
ting demand, eschewing the traditional work format, viz. working Mondays to Fridays from nine to five for a single
employer (Manyika et al., 2016). Second, they face varying degrees of capacity constraints to participate on these
platforms in what and how much they can offer because they leverage existing assets and resources, which are
nonscale-free, subject to opportunity costs (Levinthal & Wu, 2010). While the former has received much attention
from researchers (e.g., Ahsan, 2020; Burtch, Carnahan, & Greenwood, 2018; Sundararajan, 2016), studies on the
nonscale-free resources leveraged by supply-side sharing economy participants, thus constraining their production
capacity, remains conspicuously absent.
Platform owners can embed a clearly defined incentives structure, that is, rules of the game(Jacobides,
Cennamo, & Gawer, 2018), in the platform design (Ceccagnoli, Forman, Huang, & Wu, 2012; Claussen, Kretschmer, &
Mayrhofer, 2013) to ensure their success and that of supply-side complementors. Such design can motivate com-
plementors to provide both diversity in offerings as well as quality in those offerings so as to create value for buyers
(Boudreau, 2012; Boudreau & Hagiu, 2009; Cennamo, 2018). A platform design is especially crucial for platforms in
emerging economies, where complementors, faced with intense competition at an early stage, compromise the integ-
rity and quality of the offering, jeopardizing the long-term success of the entire platform ecosystem and its partici-
pants (Chu & Wu, 2018). The general lack of highly specialized business skills or knowledge to analyze complex
information (Karim, 2011; Koo & Eesley, 2017; Thai & Turkina, 2014) among microentrepreneurs in emerging
TAE ET AL.303

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT