A BURNING QUESTION: DOES ARSON INCREASE WHEN LOCAL HOUSE PRICES DECLINE?

Published date01 March 2017
AuthorMichael D. Eriksen,James M. Carson
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12089
Date01 March 2017
ABURNING QUESTION:DOES ARSON INCREASE WHEN
LOCAL HOUSE PRICES DECLINE?
Michael D. Eriksen
James M. Carson
ABSTRACT
We construct panel data on house prices and the determined cause of 4.8
million individual fires in the United States between 1986 and 2010 to test
whether decreases in local housing market prices coincided with increases in
arson. Since some insured homeowners may attempt to disguise the actual
cause of fire as accidental, we also examine how decreases in local house
prices are associated with changes in the total number of fires and the
probability of determined causes of accidental fires. For the sample period,
our results suggest that declines in local house prices coincided with
increases in arson, the total number of fires, and the probability that fires
were determined to occur due to arson and misuse. We provide further
support for the existence of such an effect with empirical evidence that the
relation between declines in house prices and arson is stronger in states that
allow mortgage lender recourse.
INTRODUCTION
Arrow (1963) first speculated that economic factors may lead some homeowners to
commit arson on their own property due to moral hazard.
1
While empirical evidence
Michael D. Eriksen is an Assistant Professor of Finance, Rawls College of Business, Texas Tech
University, Lubbock, TX 79409. James M. Carson is the Daniel P. Amos Distinguished Professor
of Insurance, Department of Insurance, Legal Studies, and Real Estate, Terry College of
Business, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602. The authors can be contacted via e-mail:
mike.eriksen@ttu.edu, jcarson@uga.edu. The authors express their appreciation and acknowl-
edge helpful comments from Andre Liebenberg and David Russell; from participants at
meetings of the Risk Theory Society, the American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Association, and the Urban Economics Association; from seminar participants at the University
of Nebraska, Illinois State University, and the University of Cincinnati; from colleagues at the
University of Georgia and Texas Tech University; and from the editor and two anonymous
reviewers.
1
Prior research provides evidence of other types of insurance-related consumer behaviors tied
to prevailing economic conditions. For example, mortality-contingent insurance contracts
(e.g., life insurance) experience increases in policy loans and surrenders during times of high
interest rates (Outreville, 1990; Liebenberg et al., 2010).
© 2015 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 84, No. 1, 7–34 (2017).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12089
7
regarding the influence of economic factors on the incidence of property crime is well
established in the prior literature (see Ehrlich, 1996), the relation between economic
conditions and arson is less clear. Volatility of house prices over time, and especially
during the Great Recession, leads naturally to the question of whether declines in
house prices are related to residential fires caused by arson. In this article, we
construct a panel data series of the determined cause of 4.8 million fires that occurred
in the United States between 1986 and 2010 to test whether decreases in local house
prices coincided with increases in arson.
2
Determining whether arson increases when house prices decrease is important given
that arson poses significant danger to human life in neighboring properties and the
firefighters attempting to extinguish the fires. In addition to the threat to human life,
arson also caused at least $684 million in property damage in 2009 according to the
National Fire Prevention Association (NFPA) (Karter, 2010).
3
Given the majority of
these damages were on insured properties, increases in arson would result in higher
losses for insurance companies and eventually higher premiums for policyholders
(Hoyt, 1990).
Our knowledge of whether a relation exists between arson and macroeconomic
conditions is limited to a relatively small number of studies beginning with
Hershbarger and Miller (1978), Spillman and Zak (1979), and Cloninger (1981). This
early research found limited and conflicting evidence using highly aggregated
national arson estimates where other unobserved trends may also be present, as
highlighted by Brotman and Fox (1988). More recently, Goebel and Harrison (2012)
provide cross-sectional evidence of a higher incidence of arson during 2007 in states
with less house appreciation between 2002 and 2006, and it is an important empirical
question as to whether their results generalize to other time periods.
Our analysis complements the cross-sectional results of Goebel and Harrison (2012)
and extends the literature in several ways. First, we assemble and use a novel panel
data series of arson offenses and accidental fires arguably subject to less reporting bias
compared to data from the Uniform Crime Reports (UCR) System used in prior
studies.
4
Second, the panel data set we create allows us to account for area- and time-
2
We focus on declines in house prices (as a proxy for negative equity) conditional upon changes
in other economic factors as Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund (2009) show that recent house price
decreases are highly correlated with the shares of homeowners with negative equity, and due
to the unique role of house prices in economic motives associated with intentional and
accidental fires. We discuss these potential mechanisms in more detail in the next section. In
our analysis of arson and declines in house prices, while it is desirable to include homeowner
insurance policy coverage characteristics, as suggested by a reviewer, our data unfortunately
do not include specific insurance contract information.
3
These estimates most likely represent the lower bound of the actual economic cost of arson
since not all instances of arson may be detected as we discuss later in this article.
4
While the UCR is the most commonly used source of data when analyzing the effect of
economic conditions on criminal offenses, various studies document instances of systematic
reporting bias (Ehrlich, 1996; Levitt, 1997; Raphael and Winter-Ebmer, 2001). This reporting
bias may be due to perceived stigma, political motivations, or police departments having
limited financial resources to submit reports (Ehrlich, 1996).
8THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT