Border tax adjustments and tariff‐tax reforms with consumption pollution

AuthorPanos Hatzipanayotou,Nikos Tsakiris,Michael S. Michael
Date01 December 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12407
Published date01 December 2019
J Public Econ Theory. 2019;21:11071125. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
1107
Received: 15 February 2019
|
Accepted: 18 October 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12407
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Border tax adjustments and tarifftax reforms
with consumption pollution
Nikos Tsakiris
1
|
Panos Hatzipanayotou
2,3
|
Michael S. Michael
3,4
1
Department of Economics, University of
Ioannina, Ioannina, Greece
2
Department of International and
European Economic Studies, Athens
University of Economics and Business,
Athens, Greece
3
Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo
Institute of Economic Research (CESifo),
Munchen, Germany
4
Department of Economics, University of
Cyprus, Nicosia, Cyprus
Correspondence
Panos Hatzipanayotou, Department of
International and European Economic
Studies, Athens University of Economics
and Business, 76, Patission street, 104 34
Athens, Greece.
Email: hatzip@aueb.gr
Abstract
We develop a model of a small open economy, where
pollution per unit of consumption between domestically
produced and imported quantities of the same good
differs. We show that the firstbest policy combination
calls for consumption taxes on all polluting goods, and
border tax adjustment (BTA) measures, that is, tariffs or
import subsidies. We identify conditions under which
wellknown tarifftax reform policies for developing
economies, such as a consumerpriceneutral piecemeal
reform of trade and a consumption tax, and a consumer
priceneutral reform of all trade and consumption taxes
improve welfare. We also evaluate whether reforms of
trade taxes alone are superior to consumerpriceneutral
reforms of trade and consumption taxes.
KEYWORDS
border tax adjustments, consumptiongenerated pollution, optimal
taxation, trade and consumption tax reforms
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F13; F18; H20; H21
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Nowadays, consumption and residential activities are considered important sources of pollution
emissions such as carbon dioxide, sulfur dioxide, and solid waste accumulation, for example,
Hu and McKitrick (2016).
1
In many cases, the same consumer needs are satisfied by different
commodities produced in different countries using different materials and technologies. The
1
In their study they note, “…According to the US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA 2012), nearly onehalf of the emissions of smogforming volatile
organic compounds (VOCs), more than half of the nitrogen oxides (NOx) emissions, and about half of the toxic air pollutant emissions in US are generated from
consumption of such different varieties of the same product produced in one country or
imported, satisfying the same consumer needs, may generate different rates of pollution per
unit of consumption. For example, different brands of automobiles, airconditioners and other
electrical appliances, tires, and so forth, produced by different firms in different countries, have
different energy requirements and thus they are attributed to different energy classifications.
2
To address this phenomenon, we construct a theoretical model of a competitive small open
economy producing and consuming many traded goods. We assume that consumption of all
commodities generates pollution emissions, while their production is a clean activity. The
distinctive element in this model is that pollution per unit of consumption between
domestically produced and imported quantities of the same good differs. Within this
framework, we show that the firstbest policy combination requires (a) consumption taxes on
all polluting goods. While consumption taxes on imported and on domestically produced
quantities of the same good are the same, they differ across commodities depending on their
rates of pollution per unit of consumption; (b) freetrade for all exportable goods, and (c) a tariff
(import subsidy) or freetrade on an importable if pollution per unit of imports consumption is
higher (lower) or the same with pollution per unit of consumption of the domestically produced
quantities of this good.
Consumption pollution can be local, for example, affecting land and rivers in the country, or
transboundary, for example, CO
2
emissions. There are reasons why a small economy that
cannot affect world commodity prices and does not generate noticeable damages to the global
climate, as a result of its own emissions, has a strong interest in curbing the levels of its
pollutants. One reason is that various polluting activities, for example, coalburning and the use
of cars running on fossil fuels, generate not only globalpollutants such as CO
2
emissions
responsible for global warming but also a number of other airborne and water contaminating
toxics, for example, mercury, lead, sulfur dioxide and other heavy metals and particulates,
which generate health and environmental damages to a large extent local in their effects.
Another reason is a small countrys commitment to curb the levels of its own emissions,
negligible or not in regard to their impact on global climate, as a result of its membership in
global climate initiatives. For example, small countries such as Austria, Cyprus, Luxembourg,
and Malta are among the signatories of the Paris Agreement to reduce greenhouse emissions,
until their total eradication, the socalled premise of zero fossil fuels,and their replacement
with renewable and alternative cleaner energy sources.
Studies which examine the optimal policies under consumption pollution externalities
propose that for small open economies, the firstbest policy combination requires an emission
tax to control for the consumption pollution externality, and free trade, for example, see Krutilla
(1991), Gulati and Roy (2008), Copeland (2011). However, more often than not, for political or
political economy reasons emission taxes may be set at suboptimal levels. For example, the
implementation of Pigouvian emission taxes is infeasible in the presence of lobbying activities
by large polluters, corruption, weak administrative capacity or technical and economic reasons,
for example, see Eisenbarth (2017), McAusland (2008), Fullerton and West (2002). In these
cases, governments can resort to other forms of taxation such as consumption and trade taxes.
3
motor vehicles. . For OECD countries, up to 90% of the total carbon monoxide (CO
2
) is from the source road(OECD Statistics 2012). The emissions related
to consumption of energy in US are accountable for about 71% of US carbon dioxide emissions.
2
Electrical devices are classified in seven energy classes (from A to G), depending on the energy they consume toward the energy they attribute.
3
Realworld evidence attests to the use of consumption taxes, for example, taxes on energyconsuming products, vehicles, mineral oils, and on transport fuels, to
encourage more environmentally responsible economic and recreational activities. For example, OECD (2014, pp. 135160), reports: Per liter total taxation
(VAT plus all other nonVAT taxes) as a percentage of the total price of premium unleaded gasoline: Australia 33.1, Canada 29.28, Germany 58.08, the UK
1108
|
TSAKIRIS ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT