Book Review: The origins of behavioural public policy

Published date01 July 2019
AuthorSita Nataraj Slavov
Date01 July 2019
DOI10.1177/0275074018797200
Subject MatterBook Review
American Review of Public Administration
2019, Vol. 49(5) 629 –630
© The Author(s) 2018
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
journals.sagepub.com/home/arp
Book Review
The year 2008 saw the peak of the financial crisis, as well as
the release of Cass Sunstein and Richard Thaler’s popular
press book, Nudge. These two events—argues Adam Oliver
in The Origins of Behavioral Public Policy—helped to thrust
behavioral economics into the policy spotlight. Economists
have traditionally held a deep respect for individuals’ prefer-
ences and argued that governments should intervene in per-
sonal choices only when those choices harm others—that is,
when there are externalities. In contrast, behavioral econom-
ics—whose intellectual history Oliver traces to the 1950s—
suggests that if people aren’t making rational choices, then
governments may be able to step in and protect them from
so-called “internalities” or harm they do to themselves.
Along these lines, Sunstein and Thaler advocated for
“nudges,” or behavioral-economics inspired policy interven-
tions that induce individuals to make better choices while
still preserving freedom. In the United States, a nudge that is
growing in popularity is automatic enrollment in retirement
plans. Concurrently, more intrusive behavioral economics-
influenced proposals such as taxes or bans on unhealthy food
or drink—policies that Oliver refers to as “shoves”—have
been discussed and sometimes adopted.
The key contribution of Oliver’s book is to bring some
intellectual rigor to this policy movement, whose initiatives
the author feels have been undertaken “in a sort of haphazard
way” (p. 164). Neither an academic text nor a popular press
book like Nudge, Oliver’s work covers the origins of both
rational choice and behavioral economics models, as well as
their policy implications, grounding each research finding
and policy implication firmly in both the history of thought
and current research. It provides a framework for thinking
about behavioral economics-inspired policy interventions. It
is intellectually thorough, while remaining accessible to
noneconomists.
Oliver begins with the origins of expected utility theory,
the rational choice approach to decision making under uncer-
tainty that underlies many economic models. Walking the
reader through the history of economic thought, he builds up
to a presentation of the key assumptions and predictions of
the standard model. Explanations are presented intuitively,
with a minimal amount of math. Oliver then covers the large
body of empirical evidence that appears to be at odds with
expected utility theory, as well as alternative theories that
may be more consistent with this evidence. For example,
individuals appear to treat gains and losses (relative to a ref-
erence point) asymmetrically, and to overweight small prob-
abilities and underweight large ones.
Oliver next turns his attention to three specific aspects
of economic modeling that have faced strong challenges.
The first is the theory of intertemporal choice, which aims
to describe how individuals make decisions whose costs
and benefits occur at different points in time (such as sav-
ing for retirement). The standard rational choice model is
inconsistent with many empirical findings; for example, it
cannot explain why many people fail to plan optimally for
retirement or stick to diets. These empirical phenomena
are more consistent with an alternative model in which
individuals place additional weight on the present moment
(“present bias”).
The second is how to evaluate individuals’ well-being.
Economic models generally assume individuals make
choices that maximize their utility, which is defined as the
sum of the subjective, instantaneous payoffs they get in each
moment. When used purely for prediction, utility maximiza-
tion need not be taken literally. But the concept of utility is
often used to evaluate individuals’ well-being under alterna-
tive policies and to inform policy decisions, such as whether
a health care intervention passes a cost-benefit analysis. Yet
empirical evidence suggests the overall value individuals
attach to an experience is different from an aggregation of
moment-to-moment utility obtained during the experience.
For example, they attach additional importance to the peak
and end of an experience, and they prefer experiences that
improve over time to those that deteriorate over time. How
much weight should policy makers attach to these evalua-
tions versus the aggregations of moment-to-moment utility?
That remains an open question.
Finally, Oliver considers the role of financial incentives in
motivation. In traditional economic theory, increasing the
financial rewards for an action makes individuals more
797200ARPXXX10.1177/0275074018797200The American Review of Public AdministrationBook Review
book-review2018
Book Review
Oliver, A. (2017). The origins of behavioural public policy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. 195 pp. $21. ISBN 9781316510261.
Reviewed by: Sita Nataraj Slavov, George Mason University, Arlington, VA, USA
DOI: 10.1177/0275074018797200

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT