Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law, by Margaret Jane Radin (Princeton University Press, 2013) 339 pp.

Date01 June 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jlse.12031
AuthorNim Razook
Published date01 June 2015
Journal of Legal Studies Education
Volume 32, Issue 2, 345–362, Summer 2015
Boilerplate: The Fine Print,
Vanishing Rights, and the Rule
of Law, by Margaret Jane Radin
(Princeton University Press, 2013)
339 pp.
Nim Razook
I. Introduction
Few anticipated such controversy from a proposed new commercial law.
When Karl Llewellyn submitted his first draft of the Uniform Commercial
Code (or UCC) to Wall Street, the downtown commercial interests screamed
“no.”1Why? Because rather than simply greasing the wheels of commerce, the
draft contained numerous consumer protection provisions.2The downtown
crowd wanted none of this regulation from the likes of a commercial code.
The tension between these two constituencies—Llewellyn, the uptown law
professor from Columbia, and his “academic reformers”3versus the “commer-
cial world downtown”4—pitted a new Code containing numerous business
David Ross Boyd Professor and Zinke Chair, Price College of Business, the University of
Oklahoma.
1See Alan R. Kamp, Uptown Act: A History of the Uniform Commercial Code: 1940-1949,51S.M.U.
L. Rev. 275, 277-82 (1998) [hereinafter Uptown]; Alan R. Kamp, Downtown Code: A History of the
Uniform Commercial Code 1949-54,49Buff. L. Rev. 359, 368-78 (2001) [hereinafter Downtown]
(both tracing the history of the preparation and early adoption in the state of New York of the
Uniform Commercial Code).
2Id.
3Kamp, Uptown,supra note 1, at 371.
4Id.
C2015 The Author
Journal of Legal Studies Education C2015 Academy of Legal Studies in Business
345
346 Vol. 32 / The Journal of Legal Studies Education
regulations and a significant amount of judicial oversight against libertarian
notions of commercial autonomy and freedom from oversight.5
This brief vignette reminds those who teach contracts and commercial
law of an important and often ignored point involving contracting. There is,
and likely will always be, a tension between judicial oversight and freedom
from such oversight in contract law and policy. Scholars have addressed
this tension in large and comprehensive works and in scores of law review
articles.6In the case of the UCC, the freedom from group wielded sufficient
power to force removal of most of the regulatory provisions. Bernard Broeker,
who represented Bethlehem Steel at the time of this debate, may have felt
vindicated by this decision. In the hearings preceding the Code’s adoption,
Broeker is quoted as stating, “I see no reason why I should not be allowed to
make an unreasonable contract...”7
In Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law,8
Margaret Jane Radin powerfully holds that the freedom of contract group
has prevailed and that consumers are the big losers. Boilerplate, notes Radin,
comprises those nonnegotiable terms found in most standard contracts,
typically formed between those with bargaining power and those without,
about which there is little negotiation or choice.9Those who enter into these
5Id. Kamp colorfully describes the setting this way: “By looking at the record somewhat differently,
the story changes from a long drafting process conducted by two remote, august, and expert
institutions into one characterized by a collision between the two cultures of Uptown and
Downtown. It is an epic in which a radical professor—a fan of folk music, a poet, a supporter of
the New Deal, a devotee of anthropologists and Veblen and Commons, the radical institutional
economists, a despiser of pallid intellectuals who instead preferred "action-direction thinking,"
and a decorated veteran of the German Army of World War I who was about to divorce his second
wife and marry one of his former students—sought to realize his radical, reformist programs for
sales law.” Kamp, Uptown, supra note 1, at 277–78.
6This note cannot begin to list even most of these works, but I have attempted throughout this
article to provide a good mix of sources. See, e.g,. Grant Gilmore, The Death of Contract
(1974) (suggesting that the classical theory of contract underpinned by full freedom of contract
no longer exists); Michael Trebilcock, The Limits of Freedom of Contract (1993) (tracing
the persistent problems such as information and power asymmetry that pose interpretive prob-
lems for courts and scholars); Friedrich Kessler, Contracts of Adhesion, 43 Colum. L. Rev. 629,
630 (1943) (noting the rise of and problems associated with standard contracts); Anthony T.
Kronman, Contract Law and Distributive Justice,89Yale L.J. 472 (1980) (addressing the tensions
between the application of libertarianism and distributive justice in contract law).
7Kamp, Downtown, supra note 1, at 373.
8Margaret Jane Radin, Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of
Law (2013).
9Id. at 9. Radin labels them contracts, but states that “labeling something a ‘contract’ doesn’t
necessary make it one.” Id. at 10. The term “standard contracts” is the prevailing label for these

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT