Bluffs, Lies, and Consequences: A Reconceptualization of Bluffing in Buyer–Supplier Negotiations

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jscm.12155
Date01 April 2018
Published date01 April 2018
BLUFFS, LIES, AND CONSEQUENCES: A
RECONCEPTUALIZATION OF BLUFFING IN BUYER
SUPPLIER NEGOTIATIONS
LUTZ KAUFMANN AND JOERG ROTTENBURGER
WHU Otto Beisheim School of Management
CRAIG R. CARTER
Arizona State University
CHRISTIAN SCHLERETH
WHU Otto Beisheim School of Management
Business negotiations constitute a key element of supply chain interactions
that can create additional value for both the buyer and supplier. However,
negotiations can also render the parties vulnerable to deception. While a large
body of knowledge on buyersupplier relationships exists, research on decep-
tion and bounded ethicality in supply chain relationships is still nascent. We
advance this new research stream in behavioral supply chain management by
first conceptualizing two types of deceptionbluffs and lies. Departing from
previous content-dependent conceptualizations/definitions, we define both as
convention-dependent, norms-based constructs: Bluffs (lies) are deceptions
that are palatable (unpalatable) to both parties in a buyersupplier negotia-
tion. Second, studies 1 and 2 of our article employ Q methodology and best
worst scaling to operationalize bluffs while refining the construct of a lie.
Third, a correlational study (study 3) examines the psychological properties/cog-
nition of a negotiator who lies, bluffs, or does neither (i.e., communicates
honestly). Fourth, a behavioral experiment (study 4) investigates the psycho-
logical consequences of bluffs, lies, and honesty for the targets. Bluffers (liars)
show low (high) degrees of moral disengagement. Targets of bluffs experience
high degrees of self-directed anger but are willing to engage in further negoti-
ations with the bluffer, while targets of lies experience high degrees of anger
directed at the liar and show a low willingness to further negotiate with the
liar. Taken together, these findings provide new insights into the dynamics of
bluffing and lying in buyersupplier negotiations.
Keywords: buyersupplier negotiations; deception; bluff; lie; social cognitive theory;
moral disengagement theory; Q methodology; bestworst scalin g; behaviora l experimen t
INTRODUCTION
Bluffing is nothing more than a form of lying
(Business executive quoted in Carr, 1968, p. 155).
Bluffing in business ... (is) simply game strategy
... it does not reflect on the morality of the bluffer
(Carr, 1968, p. 155).
Deception is omnipresent in daily life. While most
humans value honesty and wish to behave honestly,
recent studies demonstrate that almost no one is invul-
nerable to temptations to deceive (Mazar, Amir &
Ariely, 2008; Mazar & Ariely, 2006). Buyersupplier
relationships form the foundation of supply chain
The authors would like to thank the editor-in-chief, associate edi-
tor, and anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments, and
Don Lange for his comments on an early draft of this manuscript.
An earlier version of the manuscript received the 2016 Academy of
Management Conference’s Conflict Management Division’s Best
Paper Award.
April 2018 49
Journal of Supply Chain Management
2017, 54(2), 49–70
©2017 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
management (SCM) (Ellram & Cooper, 2014). The key
elements of successful collaborative buyersupplier
relationships are commitment and trust, both of which
can be negatively affected by opportunistic behavior,
such as deception, of either the buyer or the supplier
(Handley & Benton, 2012; Moberg & Speh, 2003; Mor-
gan & Hunt, 1994). Perceptions of opportunism can
even hamper buyersupplier relationships that are less
collaborative, such as those involving sealed bids and
reverse auctions (Carter & Kaufmann, 2007).
While deceptive behavior in buyersupplier relation-
ships typically inflicts damage on its target, to the bene-
fit of the actor (for an example, see Wu & Choi, 2005),
it also occasionally backfires and harms both parties.
For example, in the case of the tarnished collaboration
between Ford and Lear for the 1996 Ford Taurus (Yan
& Kull, 2015), deceptive acts led to design defects, esca-
lating costs for both parties, and, ultimately, to a
strained buyersupplier relationship. Overall, a variety
of deceptive practices exist (Carter, 2000b; Hill, Eckerd,
Wilson & Greer, 2009). Hence, there is a need for
research that distinguishes among and investigates the
different types of deception that occur in SCM contexts.
One of the key means by which buyers interface
with their suppliers is through the negotiation process
(Kaufmann & Carter, 2004; Ramsay, 2004). Negotia-
tions not only result in determining price, quality,
delivery, and other attributes of spend, but can also
set the tone for the ongoing buyersupplier relation-
ship (Zachariassen, 2008). Given their rapid and often
real-time nature, coupled with the potentially high
stakes (Thomas, Thomas, Manrodt & Rutner, 2013)
both for an organization and for the individual buyer
negotiations pose fertile grounds for deceptive
behavior (Tenbrunsel, 1998).
Despite its prevalence in buyersupplier negotiations
(Aquino & Becker, 2005), there is surprisingly little
research on deception in such contexts. The aim of
this study is twofold: first, to improve the construct
clarity of two common types of deception in business
negotiationsbluffs and lies; and second, to compare
and contrast their psychological properties and conse-
quences, demonstrating that different types of decep-
tion ultimately yield very different results for
negotiations and the buyersupplier relationships in
which they are embedded.
Following Levine and Schweitzer (2015, p. 89), we
define deception as “the transmission of information
that intentionally misleads others.” We suggest that
both bluffs and lies constitute manifestations of decep-
tion, yet differ conceptually. Research on lying has
gained traction over the past decade. However,
researchers have devoted much less attention to bluff-
ing (Guidice, Alder & Phelan, 2009), which remains
an under-researched and disputed concept (Glac, War-
ren & Chen, 2014). Thus, investigating the
psychological properties and consequences of bluffing
first requires a delineation of the term’s meaning.
The next section of the article introduces social
cognitive theory (Bandura, 1991) and moral disengage-
ment theory (Bandura, 1999) and outlines their rele-
vance to the investigation of bluffs and lies in buyer
supplier negotiations. We then provide an overview of
prior research on bluffing, concluding that the extant
literature lacks a clear definition due to its focus on the
content of the deception. Subsequently, we provide
convention-dependent, socially constructed (Berger &
Luckmann, 1966) definitions for bluffs and lies and con-
duct two studies to operationalize both: In study 1,
experts in business-to-business (B2B) negotiations indi-
cate their perceived difference between a bluff and a lie
using Q methodology (Watts & Stenner, 2012). In
study 2, we test for convergent validity of the results
using bestworst scaling (Dyachenko, Reczek &
Allenby, 2014; Louviere, Lings, Islam, Gudergan &
Flynn, 2013) using contrasting participants with little
or no experience in business negotiations. These two
studies yield prototype examples (Scott & Jehn, 2003)
of bluffs and lies, which we use next to investigate the
psychological properties of bluffing and lying for the bluf-
fer/liar, referred to as the actor (study 3), and the psycho-
logical consequences for the target of the bluff/lie (study
4). In doing so, we further refine the two constructs.
SOCIAL COGNITIVE THEORY AND MORAL
DISENGAGEMENT THEORY
Social cognitive theory (SCT) regards humans as self-
organizing, goal-setting, anticipating, and yet fallible
decision makers (Bandura, 1991). Whereas ethical theo-
ries typically are prescriptive in nature, SCT is predictive,
focusing on how humans actually behave rather than
how they ought to behave. Social cognitive theory posits
that humans are cultivating moral standards over the
course of their socialization and develop self-sanctions
on this basis. Working in an anticipatory manner, both
social and self-sanctions jointly ensure that humans are
aware of their moral standards and behave in line with
them (Bandura, 1999). Humans thereby monitor and
regulate their actions, engaging in those which provide
satisfaction and self-worth, while avoiding those that
lead to self-censure and cognitive dissonance.
Despite self-regulation, humans frequently fail to
withstand temptations and violate their own stan-
dards (i.e., bounded ethicality; Hill et al., 2009). Build-
ing on SCT, moral disengagement theory (MDT)
predicts that decision makers adhere to their moral
standards as long as their self-sanctions prove stronger
than the external incentives they are confronted with.
When the external inducements are strong, humans
face a dilemma: They wish to engage in actions that
benefit them yet harm their target, but can only do so
Volume 54, Number 2
Journal of Supply Chain Management
50

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT