Better Politicians: If We Pay, Will They Come?

AuthorDustin Rogers,Michael M. Atkinson,Sara Olfert
Published date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12117
Date01 May 2016
MICHAEL M. ATKINSON
DUSTIN ROGERS
SARA OLFERT
University of Saskatchewan
Better Politicians:
If We Pay, Will They Come?
While each election provides the Canadian House of Commons with a fresh
batch of politicians, no consideration has been given to the question of whether the qual-
ity of politicians is improving. Yet improving quality has been the focus of several
commissions urging increases in MP compensation. This article addresses the compe-
tence and compensation questions by asking whether changes in levels of compensation
might make a difference to the educational qualifications of political leaders. We assem-
ble a unique dataset of 1,291 federal politicians elected to the Canadian House of
Commons from 1993 to 2011 and show that prime ministers do have a preference for
more highly educated MPs when filling ministerial and other executive positions. Our
findings suggest that certain subgroups of MPs, particularly educated women, may be
attracted by upward shifts in compensation. We discuss the reasons for these effects and
the relative importance of compensation in career decisions.
Implicit in much of the work on political leadership is the idea that
leadership is an important variable in the production of good public pol-
icy and that removing obstacles to the recruitment of good leaders is a
worthy objective of political reformers. In sum, we would be well served
by competent leaders, and we should take measures to improve
leadership competence.
This article asks, f‌irst, whether competence is actually valued and,
second, whether higher levels of compensation are likely to attract stron-
ger, more competent politicians. In doing so, the article raises the
conceptual question of what constitutes competence and the methodo-
logical question of how to connect competence and compensation. The
latter connection may appear straightforward: increases in compensation
reduce opportunity costs for those with talent and induce them to con-
sider a life (or at least a period) in politics. Unfortunately, there is
nothing inevitable about this connection as researchers have begun to
discover (Messner and Polborn 2004). Compensation may attract better
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 41, 2, May 2016 361
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12117
V
C2016 Washington University in St. Louis
politicians, but it may also encourage those with fewer alternatives, just
as it may discourage less able incumbents from surrendering a job that
has taken a lucrative turn.
Legislative research, much of it concentrated among US state legis-
latures, has been premised on the idea that better compensation is a
feature of legislative professionalization and that the supply of compe-
tent politicians depends on it (Squire 1988). Citizen-candidate models of
political representation (Besley and Coate 1997; Osborne and Slivinski
1996) also focus on the supply side of politics. In these models, any citi-
zen can offer herself as a candidate and will do so based on a cost-
benef‌it analysis that includes a consideration of the costs of running, the
likelihood of winning, and an estimate of who else might run (Poutvaara
and Takalo 2007). Voters choose candidates whose policy preferences
resemble their own and who are presumed to be capable of implement-
ing them. Thus the model turns on the supply of competent candidates
and the incentives that would induce them to enter political life. In the
language of rational choice, candidates “must solve a dynamic optimiza-
tion problem to determine the current decision that maximizes expected
present value of lifetime utility” (Diermeier, Keane, and Merlo 2005).
Compensation, in this setup, may be important, but there are a host of
other considerations for would-be candidates, including electability and
campaign costs.
In this article, we acknowledge the empirical work on US state
legislatures but depart from the citizen-candidate model to emphasize
the role of political party leaders in recruiting candidates. Parties make
no systematic appearance in citizen-candidate models, and yet in virtu-
ally all liberal democracies, particularly parliamentary ones, parties
organize governance from the selection of candidates to the selection of
the political executive. Where the citizen-candidate model emphasizes
the supply of politicians, a party-selection model concentrates on the
demand side. What do party leaders demand in candidates? Since
Downs (1957), we have modeled parties as power-seeking blocs and
treated electability as a criterion for evaluating policies and candidates.
In parliamentary systems, party leaders also value loyalty: as Mayhew
observed over 40 years ago, in the British parliament “party loyalty is
rewarded; heresy is not” (1974, 22).
If loyalty and electability requirements are met, is there any room
left to demand competence? In parliamentary systems, competence is
valued for governing purposes, rather than electoral ones, although
effective governing presumably enhances electoral prospects. Upon
election, prime ministers must f‌ill a number of executive positions and
can do so only from a very limited pool of candidates, namely the
362 Michael M. Atkinson, Dustin Rogers, and Sara Olfert

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT