Bank secrecy in offshore centres and capital flows: Does blacklisting matter?

Published date01 January 2017
AuthorDonato Masciandaro,Olga Balakina,Angelo D’Andrea
Date01 January 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2016.09.005
Bank secrecy in offshore centres and capital ows: Does
blacklisting matter?
Olga Balakina, Angelo DAndrea, Donato Masciandaro
BocconiUniversity, Economics,via Sarfatti 25, 20146Milan, Italy
abstractarticle info
Articlehistory:
Received16 April 2015
Receivedin revised form 28 September2016
Accepted28 September 2016
Availableonline 17 October 2016
JEL classication:
F21
K42
Thisstudy analyses cross-bordercapital owsin order to verify the existenceand direction of the effectof the soft
regulationpromotedby internationalorganizations againstbanking secrecywhich characterizedthe so called tax
and nancialheavens. This effectis called in the literature StigmaEffect, but both the existenceand the direction
of thestigma effect are farfrom being obvious.The international capitalows can simplyneglect the relevanceof
the blacklisting,or worst, the attractiveness ofbanking secrecy can produce a race to thebottom: the desire to
eludemore transparent regulationcan sensibly inuencethe capital movements.We test whether being includ-
ed and laterexcluded from the FATF blacklistis an effective measurethat inuences countriescross-border cap-
ital ows. Using annual panel data for the period 19962014 , we apply our framework to 126 countries
worldwide.We nd evidence that in generalthe stigma effect does not exist.
© 2016 ElsevierInc. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Bank secrecy
Offshorecentres
Internationalcapital ows
Name andshame regulation
Money laundering
1. Introduction
On April 2016revelations of the PanamaPapers spotlightedthe role
that bankingsecrecy which is offered in the so called tax and nancial
centres andterritories perform in the global economy. The facts have
caused increasingconcern that banking secrecy lies at the centreof an
international web of illegal and criminal conduct. In parallel, several
policymakers in advanced countrie s have emphasised the need for
enforcing the blacklisting tool againstthe territories that breach trans-
parency standards. But does the blacklisting work?
Banking secrecy is anevergreen issue for the national and interna-
tional debate. In the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis the ght
against bank secrecy as well as against ta x and nancialhavens has
become a politicalpriority in advanced countries.
It is oftenthe case that internationalorganisations and nationalgov-
ernments do not have strong legal instruments to impose strict mea-
sures to prevent and combatbanking secrecy. For this reason, soft law
practices, such as blacklisting, have been introduced. The aim of the
soft law tools isto put the investigated country underintense interna-
tional nancial pressures, using th e name and shameapproach.
Under the name and shameapproach, institutional regulatoryorgani-
zations and/ornational governments disclosenames of non-compliant
countries and/or non-compliant ba nks to the public, supplementing
the disclosure with forms of of cial opprobrium (Brummer, 201 2).
This approach is increasingly applied in the international context and
it aims to address policy coord ination problems among nationa l
policymakersand regulators (Greene& Boehm, 2012).
This paper looks at cross-border capital ows in the period 1996
2014 in order to verifythe existence and the direction of the so-called
stigma effect, i.e. the effect of the blacklisting in addressing bankin g
secrecy.
Country compliance with the intern ational standards of the
blacklisting policy named Anti-MoneyLaundering and Combating the
Financing of Terrorism AML/CFT thereafter gained momentum in
the nationalpolicymaking all aroundthe world in the last twodecades.
Established by the Financial Action Task Fo rce (FATF) in 1999,
nowadays theinternational standardconsists of 49 Recommendations,
dealing respectivelywith anti-money laundering (forty recommenda-
tions) and combating terrorist n ancing (nine recommendations) .
Since 2000, FATF has periodically issued lists blacklists thereafter
of Non-Cooperative Countries and Territories(NCCTs), which identify
the jurisdictions that FATFbelieves to be non-compliant with interna-
tional best practices.
Reviewof Financial Economics 32 (2017)3057
The researchhas been supported by the BafCarenCentre, Bocconi University.The
authors warmly thank the an onymous referees for their construct ive comments and
useful insights on earli er drafts. Donato Masciandaro pleasantly ackn owledges that
actingas Consultantfor the Inter-AmericanDevelopmentBank has been a unique andpre-
ciousexperienceto enrich his knowledgeon how the blacklistingprocessconcretely inter-
acts with the nancial dynamics.The usual disclaimersare applied.
Correspondingauthor.
E-mailaddress: donato.masciandaro@unibocconi.it(D. Masciandaro).
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2016.09.005
1058-3300/©2016 Elsevier Inc. All rightsreserved.
Contents listsavailable at ScienceDirect
Review of Financial Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rfe
In order to prevent and combat illegal nancial ows, international or-
ganizations do not have hard legal commitmentsat their disposal; there-
fore they resort to blacklisting by FATF as a soft law practice. The aim of
the listing procedure is to put Black-Listed Countries (BLCs) under intense
international nancial pressure, by employing the name and shameap-
proach in order to produce the so-called stigma effect (Masciandaro, 2005,
2008). The stigma effect represents an inverse relationship between
blacklisting and international capital ows. Indeed, the event of being
blacklisteddecreases the international capitalows towards a country.
Two sources of pressures on the BLC are expectedto work.
On the one side,most countries that interact with a BLC evaluate its
nancialtransactions assuspicious. This occurrenceleads to more strin-
gent and costlymonitoring procedures.Banks operating in multipleju-
risdictionsare the most concerned by these monetarycosts, including
compliance costs. The AML/CFT cost of compliance seems to continu-
ously increase,at an average rate of about45 per cent (KPMG, 2011).
Along with monitoring costs, nancial transactionswith a BLC can
imply reputational costs.Suspiciousnancial transactions attrac t
more and more attention from supranational organizations, national
policymakers and regulators,and international media. For banking in-
stitutions, engagement in opaque nancial tra nsactions can increase
reputational risks.Just to cite some recent and meaningful episodes, it
is worth mentioningthat in 2012-15 various international bankshave
been investigated for alleged illicit nancial transactionsand ned, or
solicited, to improve their comp liance (Powell, 2013). Transacti ons
with BLCs canproduce such a kind of negativereputational effects.
Because of the potential damage caused by the stigma effect, inter-
nationalbanks may have a strongincentive to avoid businesswith BLCs.
In the same way, the stigma effect can be c onsidered as a conse-
quence of the nameand shameapproach.
However both the existence and the direction of the stigma effect
are far from beingobvious. As it was pointed out in previousstudies
(Masciandaro (2005, 2008) and Mas ciandaro, Takats, and Unger
(2007) the AML/CFT non-compliance of a country can be attractive
under specic conditions,such as the potentialexistence ofa worldwide
demandfor non-transparent nancialtransactions.A BLC can be attrac-
tive for bankingand non-banking institutions seeking to promote light-
ly regulatedproducts and servicesto their wealthyand/or sophisticated
clients. The internationalbanking industry as a whole can have incen-
tives to takeadvantages from the existenceof BLCs.
Thereforethe stigma effect,meant to be astickforall the countries
not in compliancewith the regulation,can turn out into a carrot.
The stigma paradox can emerge. A specic case of regulatory arbi-
tragethat creates the so-called raceto the bottomstrategy,which im-
plies the desire to elude more pr udent regulation (Barth, Caprio , &
Levine, 2006) and that can sensiblyinuence the international capital
movements(Houston, Lin, & Ma, 2012).
Finally,a third possibility has to be considered: the behaviourof the
international banking institutions in the cross-border business can be
simply driven by factors other than the stigma effect (Kudrle, 2009).
In this case, the stigma neutrality holds.
The relevance of the stigma effect has become increasinglyimpor-
tant in recent times, whenpolicymakers, regulators and scholars seek
to understand which institutional , regulatory and historical features
can attract or discourage internation al capital ows (Papaioannou,
2009; Reinhardt, Ricci, & Tressel, 2010; Houston et al., 2012; Qureshi,
Ostry, Ghosh, & Chamon, 2011; Mile si Ferretti & Tille, 2011; Chitu,
Eichengreen, & Mehl, 2013). The nancial effects of regulationare par-
ticularlyrelevant when the AML/CFT rulesare under discussion.
Thispaper aims to empiricallyevaluate the trend,magnitude andro-
bustness of the stigma effect, b y focusing on the impact of the FATF
blacklisting on the relationshipsbetween international nancial ows
and the BLCs bankingsystems.
So far empirical evidence is spa rse and mixed (Kudrle, 2009;
Masciandaro, 2013)with cases of stigma effect,stigma paradox and
stigma neutrality being detectedand therefore inconclusive.
To understandthe kind of inuence t hat FATF blacklisting can have
on BLCs, our research focuses on how internation al capital ows re-
spond to the stigma signals providedby the FATF. The stigma effect is
based on the assumption that blacklistingprocedures alter the attrac-
tivenessof a country for capital ows.The non-complianceof a country
with AML/CFTstandards (listing)can decrease the overallamount of -
nancial transactions (volume effect) and/or decrease its efciency to
manage thosecapitals (cost effect).Of course, the opposite canhappen
when a countryis delisted.
In this paper we aim to nd empirical evidence of whether and to
what extent FATF blacklisting affects the volume of nancial transac-
tions. Thestigma effect, as a signal thatenables to distinguishbetween
compliant and non-compliant cou ntries, can have deterring effects ,
since transactions with non-compliantcountries imply highermonitor-
ing and/or reputational costs.Observing the signal, international banks
allocate their activities accordingly. The effects of blackl isting subse-
quently manifest.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section2 contains the
review of the literature. In Section 3 we discuss our data and present
theidentication strategy.Section 4 reports the empirical model and re-
sults. Section 5 concludes.
2. Related literature
Blacklisting procedures have been introd uced in 2000. Since that
time relatively few economic studies on the stigma ef fect have been
produced.
The rst theoreticaland empiricaldiscussion of thestigma effect as a
controversialissue is found in Masciandaro(2005). The study highlight
how in the aftermath of 9/11, growing attention has been paid to the
role of lax nancial regulation in facilitating money launde ring and
the nancing of terrorism (criminalnance).
Two interactingprinciplesare commonly described in thedebate on
the relationship between money laundering and regulation: a) illegal -
nancial ows are facilitated by lax nancia l regulation; b) countries
adopting lax nancial regulation do not co-operate with the interna-
tional effort aimed at combati ng criminal nance (Internation al
MonetaryFund, 1998; Holder, 2003).These two principles characterize
the mandate of the FinancialAction Task Force (FATF) for the preven-
tion of money laundering and terrorism nance.
On the one hand, in orderto address the problems associated with
criminal nance risks, it is fundamentalto develop legal standards for
regulation. FATF standards (Re commendations) have become th e
benchmarkfor measuring thedegree of laxity of AML/CFTnancial reg-
ulation in everysingle country setting.
On theother hand, faced withthe problem of the lack ofinternation-
al harmonization and coordination , the FATF uses a list of specic
criteria in order to monitor the compliance of countries with interna-
tional standards.Those lists of compliance are commonly describedas
blacklists (Alexander, 2001; Mas ciandaro, 2005; Verdugo Yepes ,
2011). Blacklistingrepresentsthe cornerstone of the internationalregu-
lation, with the effort to reduce the risk that some countries or terri-
tories can turn into havensfor criminal nancial activities.Blacklisting
is based on the stigma effect,i.e. the threat for a listed country to face
a drop in capitalinows and then the erosion ofits competitive advan-
tage after the inclusion in the list (Hampton & Christensen, 2002).
Here the possibility of the stigma paradox occurs. Focusing on the
supplyof regulation, thestudy notes that variousjurisdictions,notwith-
standing the blacklisting threat, delay or fail to change their nancial
rules,conrming their non-cooperative attitude(reluctant friend effect).
Furthermore, although the fact that most jurisdictions in the blacklist
enact regulatory measuresin an effort to be removed from it, it remains
to be proven that regulatory reformsare sufcient to guarantee a real
change in the countrynon-cooperative attitude, with a decreasingap-
peal for black capital ows (false friend effect). The existence of these
31O. Balakinaet al. / Review of Financial Economics32 (2017) 3057

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT