Bank levy and bank risk‐taking

Published date01 September 2017
Date01 September 2017
AuthorMichael Diemer
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2017.06.001
Review of Financial Economics 34 (2017) 10–32
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Review of Financial Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rfe
Bank levy and bank risk-taking
Michael Diemer
University of Leipzig, Institute for Theoretical Economics, Grimmaische Straße 12, Leipzig D-04109, Germany
ARTICLE INFO
Article history:
Received 15 February 2015
Received in revised form 6 November 2016
Accepted 4 June 2017
Available online 17 June 2017
JEL classification:
D82
G21
G28
Keywords:
Bank levy
Competition
Moral hazard
Transparency
ABSTRACT
In the aftermath of the recent financial crisis, several countries implemented a bank levy. This paper studies
the impact of different types of bank levies on the risk-taking behaviour of banks competing in the market
for secured or unsecured debt à la Hotelling. We differentiate between three types of bank levies: a levy
on secured liabilities, a levy on unsecured liabilities and a levy on risk-weighted assets. Banks collect funds
and invest in either a prudent or a gambling asset. We find that a levy on secured and unsecured liabilities
can prevent banks from investing in the gambling asset. A levy on risk-weighted assets also induces banks
to behave more prudently. Such a levy is even more effective than a levy on liabilities if banks are well-
capitalized. Finally, a guarantee on debt makes a bank levy more effective.
© 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
During the recent financial crisis, some major banks were bailed
out in order to avoid a break-down of the financial system. Such bank
bailouts are costly for at least two reasons. Firstly, they increase fis-
cal costs (Honohan & Klingebiel, 2003). Secondly, they may change
the risk-taking incentives of banks. In response to these costs, many
countries, such as Germany, France, Sweden and United Kingdom
had introduced a bank levy which forced banks to participate in
the financing of crisis resolution measures (OECD, 2013). The design
of these charges differed significantly between these countries. In
Sweden and Germany, for instance, the levy was based on banks’
liabilities (and derivatives). In Austria, the levy was based on cap-
ital assets and on derivatives and in France, risk-weighted assets
were levied. Some countries excluded secured liabilities, such as the
Netherlands, Belgium and UK while others included these liabili-
ties (e.g. Finland, Cyprus and Hungary). Moreover, in some countries,
such as Germany, there was a minimum levy which was inde-
pendent of the banks’ financial performance. In the course of the
implementation of a new regulatory framework in the European
E-mail address: diemer@wifa.uni-leipzig.de (M. Diemer).
Union (EU), the rules specifying the bank levy were harmonized. The
annual contributions paid by European banks depend on the size and
the risk profile of these institutions. In general, the European bank
levy is based on the banks’ liabilities excluding regulatory capital and
covered deposits, whereby the risk profile of the institution shall be
taken into account.1
This paper studies and compares the impact of three different
types of bank levies on the risk-taking behaviour of banks: a levy on
secured liabilities, a levy on unsecured liabilities and a levy on risk-
weighted assets. Although, this paper does not explicitly analyse the
effects of the levy designed by the European regulators, we aim at
accounting for the two key ingredients of the European levy: the size
of the bank and its risk profile. While the first one is captured in all
three types of bank levy presented in this paper, the levy on risk-
weighted assets accounts for the risk profile of the bank. We use a
setup à la Hotelling (1929) and apply a similar framework as Repullo
(2004), where banks compete in the debt market. This setup enables
us to endogenize the costs for secured and unsecured debt and to
1See Article 103 of Directive 2014/59/EU of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 15 May 2014 establishing a framework for the recovery and resolution of
credit institutions and investment firms, OJ L 173, 12.6.2014, p. 190–348.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2017.06.001
1058-3300/© 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
M. Diemer / Review of Financial Economics 34 (2017) 10–32 11
examine who effectively pays the levy. Banks compete in the market
for secured or unsecured debt and invest their funds in either a pru-
dent or a gambling asset.2The key question examined in this paper is
whether the different types of bank levies induce banks to invest in
the prudent or in the gambling asset. The revenue-generation motive
is beyond the scope of this paper.
We obtain the following results: A levy on secured liabilities can
prevent banks from investing in the gambling asset if this levy does
not depend on the banks’ financial performance. Otherwise, their
risk decision is not affected by the levy. Both types of levies, i.e.
performance-related and performance-unrelated levy, induce banks
to lower deposit rates in order to compensate for the charge. How-
ever, the size of the compensations differs. If the levy depends on
the financial performance, the compensation is not affected by the
banks’ risk decision. By contrast, if the levy does not depend on the
banks’ financial performance banks risk to pay the charge effectively
as they cannot pass the burden to the depositors in case the projects
are not successful. This risk of being charged effectively is trans-
ferred to the depositors by a lower deposit rate. As the risk of being
charged effectively is higher for gambling banks, they decrease their
deposit rates more than prudent banks which makes gambling banks
less attractive for depositors. A levy on unsecured debt also increases
risk-taking incentives if banks are opaque. Transparent banks always
coordinate towards the prudent equilibrium and a bank levy does
not change risk incentives. However, a bank levy has an impact if
the government guarantees on debt. On the one hand, such a guar-
antee induces banks to gamble (direct effect). On the other hand it
makes the bank levy more effective by increasing the marginal effect
of the levy on banks’ risk-taking (indirect effect). A levy on banks’
risk-weighted assets can also decrease risk-taking. It is even more
effective in inducing prudent behaviour than a levy on liabilities if
banks are well-capitalized.
Thus, the present paper can contribute to the discussion about
the effects of a bank levy and its optimal design. A key contribution
of this paper is to analyse the interaction of different types of bank
levy with other regulatory instruments in the context of risk-taking
behaviour. Different types of bank levy have been discussed in the
literature. Weder di Mauro (2010) and Acharya, Pedersen, Philippon,
and Richardson (2013) propose a systemic risk charge, which only
addresses systemic banks in either form, thereby internalizing the
externality of too-big-to-fail institutions. Acharya et al. (2013) argue
that a tax on systemic risk could be based on the expected loss a bank
may incur in a financial crisis. Shin (2010) suggests a tax on non-core
liabilities which would lower banks’ risk-taking incentives because
non-core liabilities are more expensive than core liabilities. Perotti
and Suarez (2009) propose liquidity risk charges depending on the
maturity of fundings because short-term uninsured liabilities induce
fire sales in a crisis and thus increase financial distress. Gorton and
Huang (2004) suggest a tax on high-value, i.e. projects with a high
payoff, but illiquid projects.
However, risk charges may not only affect banks, but also their
customers and investors. Therefore, we also examine who pays effec-
tively the charge. For example, Albertazzi and Gambacorta (2010)
find that a part of the income tax is shifted to the banks’ customers.
Similarly, Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga (1999) provide empirical
evidence that corporate taxes (direct taxes on banks) are passed on
to banks’ customers and thus do not negatively impact banks’ prof-
its. However, the burden shift may not only take place in the case of
direct taxes, such as income taxes, but also if indirect taxes, such as
2The differentiation between secured and unsecured debt is important because
unsecured creditors take the banks’ risk-taking into account and therefore may
influence the impact of a levy on banks’ risk behaviour.
reserves on liabilities, are required (Fama, 1985; James, 1987). Buch,
Hilberg, and Tonzer (2016) provide evidence for the German bank
levy that such a levy has an impact on the deposit rates paid by banks.
Whether charges are effective in reducing the banks’ risk-taking
also depends on how these charges interact with other regula-
tory instruments. In this paper, we consider three instruments:
bank competition, subordinated debt and government guarantee.
The impact of competition on bank risk-taking has been exten-
sively assessed in the recent years (Boyd & De Nicoló, 2005; Hell-
mann, Murdock, & Stiglitz, 2000; Keeley, 1990; Martinez-Miera &
Repullo, 2010). This relationship is ambiguous since competition in
the deposit market has effects on banks’ risk-taking behaviour which
are different from the effects of competition in the loan market. This
ambiguity is also shown in empirical studies (Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt,
& Levine, 2006; Berger, Klapper, & Turk-Ariss, 2009; Jiménez, Lopez,
& Saurina, 2007).
Subordinated debt can also have a disciplinary effect as depos-
itors may penalize excessive risk-taking through requiring higher
deposit rates for riskier banks or through restrictive covenants in
bank contracts (Goyal, 2005; Peria & Schmukler, 2001). However,
debt holders may only discipline banks if they are able to monitor
changes in bank risk-taking and if banks are able to commit to a cer-
tain risk-taking (Blum, 2002; Flannery & Sorescu, 1996). Contingent
debt instruments which convert into equity in case of a trigger event
may also have a disciplinary effect.3Hilscher and Raviv (2014) show
that appropriate choice of contingent capital parameters can elimi-
nate stockholders’ incentives to increase risk. Comparing contingent
capital with debt instruments, they find that the latter one induces
higher risk-taking than properly designed contingent capital instru-
ments. Pennacchi et al. (2014) analyse the impact of a call option
enhanced reverse convertible which convert to new equity shares if
an issuing bank’s market value of total capital to deposits falls below
a pre-determined threshold. In their setup, initial shareholders have
the option to purchase these new shares. They find that contingent
capital is more efficient in reducing moral hazard than coco bonds
and non-convertible subordinated debt. Berg and Kaserer (2015) find
that coco bonds may even increase risk-taking incentives.
However, the disciplining effects may weaken or even disappear
if debt holders are secured by either a deposit insurance or govern-
ment guarantees (Acharya, Anginer, & Warburton, 2016; Anginera,
Demirguc-Kunt, & Zhu, 2014; Berger & Turk-Ariss, 2015; Nier & Bau-
mann, 2006; Sironi, 2003). This may be a key concern of policymak-
ers when implementing and labelling new regulatory instruments
as they may make explicit that a guarantee provided by the gov-
ernment or a central bank exists what currently is at most implicit.
While new resolution tools may weaken market participants’ expec-
tations that banks or creditors are covered by an implicit guarantee,
other regulatory reforms such as the implementation of a bank levy
may boost expectations that credit institutions may receive financial
support in times of distress even though it is not (explicitly) intended
by the regulators. In the presented paper, we also analyse the impact
of a bank levy on banks’ risk-taking in the presence of an implicit or
explicit guarantee on debt and we thereby aim at contributing to the
(political) discussion about the interaction between new regulatory
reforms and (implicit) guarantees (Financial Stability Board, 2013;
Lambert, Ueda, Deb, Gray, & Grippa, 2014; Schich & Aydin, 2014).
The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 introduces the model
and Section 3 analyses the effects of a levy on secured debt on
3Different types of contingent capital instruments have been discussed which
mainly differ in the trigger event. For example, these trigger events may be the issuer’s
capital ratio or market triggers such as the issuer’s stock price and financial institu-
tions indices (Flannery, 2016; Hilscher & Raviv, 2014; McDonald, 2013; Pennacchi,
Vermaelen, & Wolff,2014; Sundaresan &Wang, 2015), whereby the current regulatory
framework considers contingent capital instruments as debt securities that convert
into equity if equity or regulatory capital falls below a certain threshold (coco bonds).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT