Asymmetric cultural discounting and pattern of trade in cultural products: Empirical evidence in motion pictures

Date01 November 2019
Published date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12861
AuthorSunny Y. Shin,Jordi McKenzie
3350
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2019;42:3350–3367.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12861
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Asymmetric cultural discounting and pattern of
trade in cultural products: Empirical evidence in
motion pictures
Sunny Y.Shin
|
JordiMcKenzie
Department of Economics,Macquarie University, Sydney, NSW, Australia
KEYWORDS
cultural discount, cultural trade, home market effect, motion pictures
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The home market effect (Helpman & Krugman, 1985; Krugman, 1980) predicts that a country with
larger demand net exports in the monopolistically competitive industry as a result of interaction be-
tween increasing returns to scale and transport costs. While most empirical applications have been on
the manufacturing sector (Davis & Weinstein, 1999, 2003; Feenstra, Markusen, & Rose, 2001; Hanson
& Xiang, 2004; Head & Ries, 2001), studies on the home market effect in the service sector have also
emerged. In particular, US dominance in the global audio‐visual industry has been considered in a
number of studies (Hanson & Xiang, 2009; Lee & Waterman, 2007).1
In applying the home market effect to the audio‐visual sector (or other service sectors where trans-
port costs are negligible), it is necessary to introduce some other type of trade friction that replaces the
role of transport costs. For example, this could be a measure of ‘cultural discount’ as considered by
Rauch and Trindade (2009). Cultural discounting represents the tendency for consumers to value for-
eign cultural products less because it is difficult to appreciate unfamiliar social values and/or lan-
guages.2 Cultural discounting can be considered as a type of trade friction in the consumption of
1 The large domestic film market of the US has been identified as an explanation for the global dominance of Hollywood
films, for example, Wildman and Siwek (1988) and Hoskins and Mirus (1988).
2 The idea that cultural difference plays a role in determining the trade volume is not unique to trade in cultural products. For
example, it is a conventional practice in estimating the gravity equation to include cultural variables such as the use of
common language.
This paper is a revised version of Sunny Y. Shin's PhD thesis. Earlier versions were presented at: (a) Association of Cultural
Economics International Conference, Montreal (June, 2014); (b) Sydney University, Sydney (November, 2015); (c) 17th
Mallen Conference of Filmed Entertainment Conference, New York (November, 2015); (d) Association of Cultural
Economics International Conference, Valladolid (June, 2016); (e) Portsmouth University (July, 2016); and (f) European
Workshop on Cultural Economics, Krakow (September, 2017). We thank the editor and the anonymous reviewer for valuable
comments that improved our final manuscript.
|
3351
SHIN aNd MCKENZIE
cultural products such as films, music, books and so on.3 Although interchangeably used in some
contexts, our understanding is that the concept of cultural discount differs from cultural distance or
cultural proximity: the former is about familiarity, whereas the latter, similarity. Generally speaking,
similarity would enhance familiarity, and however, the two do not necessarily refer to the same thing.
Although the home market effect under cultural discount, which can be considered as a special
case of the original proposition, provides a seemingly intuitive explanation of US dominance in the
global audio‐visual sector, there are two strong reasons that suggest it is not the only channel that
determines the pattern of trade in the film industry. First, the global market share of US films has
been increasing despite the declining relative size of US domestic film market over the last decade or
so (Walls & McKenzie, 2012), which is the opposite to the predictions implied by the home market
effect. Second, the home market effect itself does not explain other cases of unbalanced trade patterns,
where smaller economies are net exporters or larger non‐US. countries are net importers. For example,
the home market effect does not have a say as to why the UK net exports films to China.
In this paper, we relax the assumption of cultural discount symmetry in the home market effect
model and propose asymmetric cultural discounting as another channel through which the pattern of
trade in cultural products is determined. Asymmetry in cultural discounting addresses the commonly
observed phenomenon that the appreciation on culture between two countries is not mutual.4 Although
in different language, asymmetric cultural discounting has been discussed in a number of studies as a
potential explanation for the imbalance in trade in cultural products (Frank, 1992; Hoskins & Mirus,
1988; Schulze, 1999). To date, such an effect has not been addressed within new trade theory. We in-
corporate this idea into the standard home market effect model (Helpman & Krugman, 1985) and
propose that, in addition to the home market effect, a country whose cultural contents are relatively
less discounted (i.e. more appreciated by or accessible to foreign consumers)5 tends to become a net
exporter in the service sector under increasing returns to scale.
We test for asymmetric cultural discount (‘cultural discount effect’ henceforth) using international
box office revenues given that the film industry satisfies many of the assumptions of the theoretical
model. We find evidence that supports the existence of this effect. Notably, a country that produces
films that are less culturally discounted (i.e. more accessible) tends to have a higher production share
against its trading partner. In operationalising the degree of asymmetry in cultural discount, we de-
velop a proxy based on tourist‐arrival statistics.
In Section 2, we outline the theoretical model and empirical specification. In Section 3, we explain
data and present a preliminary analysis. In Section 4, we present estimation results along with identi-
fication issues. In Section 5, we summarise and conclude.
2
|
THEORY
2.1
|
Model with asymmetric cultural discounting
In predicting the pattern of trade in cultural products, we modify and extend the seminal home market
effect model (Helpman & Krugman, 1985, Section 10.4, ‘the reference model’ hereafter) by replacing
3 The term ‘cultural discount’ was initially coined by Hoskins and Mirus (1988) in explaining the US dominance in television
programming trade.
4 Why this asymmetry occurs is out of scope in this paper but is an interesting question. Some explanation can be found in
Hoskins and Mirus (1988) who illustrate accounts for low/high cultural discount applied to the US exports/imports of TV
programmes.
5 One may view this notion of cultural accessibility in relation to that of ‘cultural hegemony’.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT