As you like it: Explaining the popularity of life‐cycle funds with multi cumulative prospect theory

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rmir.12122
AuthorStefan Graf,Stefan Schelling,Jochen Ruß
Published date01 July 2019
Date01 July 2019
© 2019 The American Risk and Insurance Association
Risk Manag Insur Rev. 2019;22:221238. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rmir
|
221
Received: 14 November 2018
|
Revised: 3 April 2019
|
Accepted: 23 April 2019
DOI: 10.1111/rmir.12122
FEATURE ARTICLE
As you like it: Explaining the popularity of
lifecycle funds with multi cumulative
prospect theory
Stefan Graf
1
|
Jochen Ruß
1,2
|
Stefan Schelling
2
1
Institute for Finance and Actuarial
Sciences, Ulm, Germany
2
Institute of Insurance Science, Ulm
University, Ulm, Germany
Correspondence
Stefan Schelling, Institute of Insurance
Science, Ulm University,
Helmholtzstrasse 20, 89081 Ulm,
Germany.
Email: stefan.schelling@uni-ulm.de
Abstract
Lifecycle (or targetdate) funds are funds, which
typically decrease their risk exposure over time. They
have been very successful in many countries, particu-
larly in the segment of old age provision. However,
ExpectedUtilityTheory(EUT)cannotexplaintheir
popularity. Moreover, recent results of Graf (2016),
imply that not only EUT but also its behavioral
counterpart Cumulative Prospect Theory (CPT) is
often not able to explain the popularity of these
products, since for each lifecycle fund a correspond-
ing balanced fund can be constructed, which is
preferable from the investors perspective in most
circumstances. In a recent paper, Ruß and Schelling
(2018), have argued that potential future changes in
an investments value already impact the decision of
longterm investors at outset. Based on this, they have
introduced Multi Cumulative Prospect Theory
(MCPT), which is based on CPT and considers the
subjective utility generated by annual value changes.
This paper shows that for MCPTinvestors, lifecycle
funds are typically more attractive than their corre-
sponding balanced funds since they reduce the
potential losses toward the end of the investment
horizon. Hence, our findings provide an explanation
------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
for inferior decisions in old age provision. This can
serve as a basis to improve such decisions.
KEYWORDS
Cumulative Prospect Theory, lifecycle funds, mental accounting, old
age provision, retirement saving
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D14; D81; G11; G22; G41; J26; J32
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Results in Graf (2016), who has analyzed lifecyclefundsforsingleandregularcontributionsand
under different asset models, imply that for any given lifecycle fund, a rational investor
(maximizing expected utility) can find a corresponding superior balanced fund. Nevertheless, life
cycle funds have been and continue to be extremely successful. A study by Yang et al. (2015) shows
that assets under management of lifecycle funds in the United States have steadily increased from
roughly$100bnin2006to$700bnin2014.Oneofthereasonsforthissuccessisthatalarge
number of pension plans allocate their contributions to these lifecycle funds, sinceaccording to
Charlson et al. (2010)96% of the large
1
pension plans in the US selected lifecycle funds as their
default asset allocation and most of the money allocated in these funds is left in the same fund until
retirement. However, Mitchell et al. (2009) show that default options alone cannot explain the
demand since lifecycle funds are also frequently chosen when no default option exists.
The results of Graf (2016)
2
imply that in most cases, the sharp contrast between optimal
utility maximizing behavior (in terms of terminal wealth)that is, not invest in lifecycle
fundsand observed actual behaviorthat is, invest in lifecycle fundscan also not be
explained by Cumulative Prospect Theory (CPT), the most popular behavioral counterpart to
Expected Utility Theory (EUT) that was introduced by Tversky and Kahneman (1992).
Several authors pointed out that investors tend to reevaluate their investment regularly, cf.,
for example, Benartzi and Thaler (1995)or Gneezy and Potters (1997). In a recent paper, Ruß and
Schelling (2018) have argued thatparticularly for rather long investment horizonsinvestors
also get subjective utility and disutility from interim value gains and losses. They argue that this
already impacts the investment decision at outset and develop a modification of CPT that
considers potential future value fluctuations already in the decision making. They show thattheir
socalled Multi Cumulative Prospect Theory (MCPT) is able to explain the demand for certain
complex guaranteed products thatare very popular in many markets but should not be desired by
either rational investors or CPTinvestors. Since lifecycle funds and balanced fundseven if they
were designed to have a similar probability distribution of terminal wealthsignificantly differ
with respect to the distributions of the potential value changes over time, they would create
significantly different subjective utility for an MCPTinvestor. The present paper therefore
analyzes how such an investors choice differs from a rational investor or a CPTinvestor.
1
Defined as including more than 5,000 employees.
2
Graf (2016) finds stochastic dominance for a single premium investment in a BlackScholes economy and practical
stochastic dominance for regular premium investments when (far) upper and lower tails of the distribution are ignored
(cf. Figure 1 for a comparison of the resulting cumulated distribution functions).
222
|
GRAF ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT