Artificial Intelligence and Human Flourishing

AuthorCharles M. A. Clark,Aleksandr V. Gevorkyan
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12356
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
Artificial Intelligence and
Human Flourishing
By Charles M. a. Clark* and aleksandr V. GeVorkyan
abstraCt. The polarization of the debate about artificial intelligence
(AI) pulls in two mutually exclusive directions of either complete
takeover of future jobs by omnipotent algorithms or an absolute
bliss with robots at work while humans reap the benefits of endless
vacation. Add this to conflicting views of work as either a disutility
to be minimized or as an essential component in human flourishing,
and it is no wonder a wide range of views are expressed on AI and
human flourishing. The literature, from Smith to Keynes and beyond,
offers some initial methodological guidance. Still, the true social and
economic implications of an AI-type environment in production and
labor markets are yet to be fully understood. This article argues that
neither of the predictions are realistic. Instead, the global economy may
be passing, albeit at a faster speed, through a phase of technological
change, similar to those experienced before. While a nuanced balance
is emerging, with an emphasis on human skills in future employment,
the benefits may not be equitably distributed, as equality of
opportunities for human development may not be reachable, though
visible, in the AI-driven society. Hence, as firms seek efficiency gains,
much weight is shifted onto governments and quasi-private entities in
maintaining decent living standards conducive to human flourishing in
unprecedented times of the COVID-19 pandemic. The article reviews
various popular concerns and advances new public policy measures
aimed at tackling some of the immediate fears of automation.
***
[J]ust when humanity possesses the scientific and technical capacities to
achieve a justly distributed well-being, in accordance with how it was
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 79, No. 4 (September, 2020).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12356
© 2020 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
*Professor of economics, Department of Economics & Finance, Tobin College of
Business, St. John’s University. Email: clarkc@stjohns.edu
Henry George Chair of economics and associate professor, Department of Economics
& Finance, Tobin College of Business, St. John’s University. Email: gevorkya@stjohns.edu
1308 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology
delivered by God, we observe instead an exacerbation of conflicts and an
increase in inequality.
Pope Francis (2019)
I. Introduction
The prospects of a world without work has long been a utopian dream.
Outside of God providing manna from heaven while the Israelites
escape from Egypt (Exodus 16:1-36), the primary way humans have
“freed” themselves from having to work is by the forced servitude or
enslavement of another group of humans. The promise, we are told,
of “artificial intelligence” (AI) is that it can turn all humans into “mas-
ters,” with machines being the servants (Danaher 2019). The fear is
that, once machines gain “general intelligence,” they will become the
masters, and humanity will be enslaved. The reality of AI is most likely
somewhere between a world of prosperity without effort and the plot
for The Terminator or similar movies.
Yet to fully evaluate the implications of AI we must first reflect on
the meaning of work and its relation to the human experience. Do
we want a world without work? Or is work somehow necessary for
human flourishing? Is AI just another technological development, no
different from the wheel and other major technological developments
in human history? These questions are based on how we understand
human nature and what constitutes human flourishing. How we un-
derstand these issues will shape how we will investigate the economic
and social implications of AI.
In the next section, this article will look at the relationship be-
tween work and human flourishing, contrasting the methodological
perspectives of neoclassical economic theory and Catholic social
thought. We are not contrasting two competing economic theories,
but instead two “visions” of human nature and society upon which
economic theories can be constructed. In the third section, we will
briefly examine some examples of economists looking at earlier major
technological changes. We will show that taking a broader view of
human nature and society—as Catholic social thought does—raises
1309Artificial Intelligence and Human Flourishing
issues economists typically ignore, issues that are fundamental to the
concerns raised by technological unemployment and AI. Section IV
examines the contemporary context of measuring AI impact on the
economy and labor markets. Section V explores one of the most crit-
ical aspects of AI’s recent march, namely, the problem of deepening
social and economic inequalities. Section VI discusses the polarity
of outcomes as we assess the key implications of AI on workers, the
economy, public policy, and human flourishing, as well as unprec-
edented challenges raised by the COVID-19 pandemic. Section VII
concludes the article.
II. Human Nature and Work
Artificial intelligence is not the beginning of this story. In the early
1800s, the “machinery question” was one of the central political
issues, one that has shaped the history of economics in profound
ways (Berg 1980). The replacing of skilled workers with machines and
with unskilled women and children created not only great economic
disruption but also considerable political unrest, most famously with
the Luddite Riots of 1813–1817. Destroying machines was made a cap-
ital offense. Most economists at the time felt that the new technology
would not cause a negative impact on employment, but there were
notable exceptions: Sismonde, Say, and Malthus all saw possible nega-
tive effects, and David Ricardo famously pronounced that the working
class could be harmed by the introduction of machines. Yet all (except
Sismonde) thought that the compensating gains of the new technol-
ogy, in terms of cheaper goods and England’s competitive advantages,
outweighed any negative effects.
In 1803, Jean-Baptiste Say ([1834] 2017: 52) raised what is one of
the central concerns of AI today, the possibility that machines could
entirely replace workers:
It may be allowable to add, that viewing human labor and machinery in
the aggregate, in the supposition of the extreme case, viz. that machinery
should be brought to supersede human labor altogether, yet the numbers
of mankind would not be thinned; for the sum total of products would
be the same, and there would probably be less suffering to the poorer

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT