Are sequential round‐robin tournaments discriminatory?

Date01 February 2019
Published date01 February 2019
AuthorMarco Sahm
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12308
S
44 © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet Journal of Public Economic Theory. 2019;21:4461.
Received:13 September 2017 Accepted:13 April 2018
DOI:10.1111/jpet.12308
ARTICLE
Are sequential round-robin tournaments
discriminatory?
Marco Sahm1,2
1Universityof Bamberg, Department of Eco-
nomics,Feldkirchenstraße 21, D96052 Bam-
berg,Germany
2CESifo,Poschingerstraße 5, D81679 Munich,
Germany
Correspondence
MarcoSahm, Department of Economics,
Universityof Bamberg, Feldkirchen-
straße21, D96052 Bamberg, Germany.
Email:Marco.Sahm@uni-bamberg.de
I examine sequential round-robin tournaments with three and four
symmetric players. Each player is matched once with each other
playerand each match is organized as a Tullock contest. A single prize
is allocated to the player with the most matches won. I show that,
depending on the position of their matches in the sequence of the
tournament, the players'ex ante winning probabilities and expected
payoffs differ. Compared to tournaments with matches organized
as all-pay auctions, however, discrimination is weaker and partially
reversed. Moreover, aggregate effort in tournaments with suitable
Tullockcontests is larger than in tournaments with all-pay auctions.
The fairness of round-robin tournaments may be improved by an
endogenous sequence of matches or the requirement that playersfix
their effort ex ante.
1INTRODUCTION
Around-robin tournament, also referred to as an all-play-all tournament, is a form of competition in which each par-
ticipant is matched with each other participant in a pairwise contest, the participants are ranked according to the
number of matches won, and awarded prizes according to this ranking. Round-robin tournaments are widely used
as an organizational form of competition, particularly in sports. Most sports leagues around the world are—at least
partially—organized as some version of a round-robin tournament. Prominent examples of double round-robin tour-
naments include the major European football leagues in England, Spain, Germany, and Italy.Moreover, smaller pure
round-robin tournaments are embedded in early stages of many multistage sports tournaments; e.g., the first round
(group stage) of the Fédération Internationale de Football Association (FIFA) World Cup (since 1950) and Union of
European Football Associations European Championship (since 1980) with four teams per group, or the second round
of the FIFAWorld Cup (1982) with three teams per group.1In tournaments with three teams, the natural schedule of
the matches is sequential. And even in tournaments with four teams, the matches are mostly scheduled sequentially
due to technological constraints (better accessibility) or economic considerations (higher profitability).2
1InJanuary 2017, FIFA decided that, from 2026 on, it will extend its World Cup to 48 teams and organize the first round in form of round-robin tournaments
withthree teams per group.
2Withfour teams, as inthe examples mentioned above, often only the last two matches are played simultaneously in order to avoid certain teams havingthe
advantageof knowing the results of other teams.
t
o
t
c
t
t
s
w
a
o
p
e
s
i
m
t
i
t
c
f
u
t
c
n
t
c
p
i
f
p
e
t
m
e
t
b
3
4
a
5
L
6
w
p
o
a
7
SAHM 3
45
1.
r
-
e
d
t
r
-
e
d
o
f
d
o
f
y
t
s
e
One reason for its high popularity may be the common wisdom according to which “a round-robin tournament is
the fairest way to determine the champion among a known and fixed number of participants. Each participant, player
or team, has equal chances against all other opposites” (Wikipedia3, 2016). This paper addresses the question whether
this common wisdom is true. Are round-robin tournaments really fair? Or is their sequential structure inherently dis-
criminatory?
Despite the practical and scientific relevanceof round-robin tournaments, the economic analysis of sequential con-
tests has mainly focused on other forms of dynamic battles like elimination tournaments or races.4An exception is
the article by Krumer, Megidish, and Sela (2017a) who investigatethe winning probabilities and expected payoffs in
sequential round-robin tournaments with three and four symmetric players and a single prize.5The different pair-
wise matches take place one after the other and the player with the most victories receives the prize. The authors
assume that each single match is organized as an all-pay auction (APA)and find substantial discrimination by the order
of matches in the subgame perfect equilibrium of such APA tournaments. For example,they show that in the three-
player tournament, the player who competes in the first and last match has a much higher winning probability and
expected payoff than the two other players.Indeed, Krumer and Lechner (2017) provide some empirical evidence for
such discrimination in round-robin sports tournaments.
Thesefindings are in stark contrast to the common wisdom of fairness.6The intuition is that the sequential structure
implies an asymmetry in intermediate scores that discourages trailing participants from providingequivalent effort as
they (anticipate having to) face some competitor with a head start who thus has a higher ex interim winning probabil-
ity.7In the model of Krumer et al. (2017a), this discouragementeffect is particularly strong because the contest suc-
cess function of an APA that determines the players'winning probabilities in each single match of the tournament is
fully discriminatory in the sense that the player with the highest effort wins for sure. This raises the question whether
the sequential round-robin tournament will be fairer if its matches are organized as contests with less discriminatory
contest success functions.
In this paper,I address the fairness issue under the assumption that the matches of the sequential round-robin tour-
nament are organized as Tullock contests. I find that such Tullocktournaments are discriminatory as well. Quantita-
tively,however, in Tullock tournaments with sufficiently low discriminatory powers (i.e., exponents),the extent of dis-
crimination, as measured by the relative standard deviations of the players'exante winning probabilities or expected
payoffs, is smaller than in APA tournaments. Intuitively, the discouragement of trailing participants will be mitigated
if the respective contests are less discriminatory because the winning probability and expected payoff of a player is
positive evenif he invests less than his opponent.
Moreover, the analysis shows that the discriminatory power of the contest success function impacts not only the
extentbut also the direction of discrimination. For example, in the three-player tournament with lottery contests (LCs),
the player who competes in the first and last match has the lowest winning probability and expected payoff—thedia-
metric opposite result to what Krumer et al. (2017a) find for tournaments with APAs.
Besides aiming at a fair tournament, the designer of a (sports) contest may be interested in (expected) aggregate
effort because more intense competition attracts more attention from viewers and sponsors. As is well known from
the literature on rent dissipation, a static winner-take-all contest between a finite number of symmetric players will
be more intense if it is organized as an APA than as a LC. However, the opposite is true if players are sufficiently
3Accessedat https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Round-robin_tournament on 16/12/2016
4Therelated literature is summarized, e.g., by Konrad (2009, chapter 8). More recent contributions include, i.e., Ghosh and Stong (2018) and Walker,Wooders,
andAmir (2011).
5Three recent working papers discuss the role of multiple prizes in round-robin tournaments (Dagaev & Zubanov,2017; Krumer, Megidish, & Sela, 2017b;
Laica,Lauber, & Sahm, 2017).
6Here, fairness is considered from a horizontal perspective:a tournament will be called (horizontally) fair,if ex ante symmetric players have equal ex ante
winning probabilities and expectedpayoffs. In reality, players are usually not symmetric. One might thus additionally require some kind of vertical fairness:a
playerwho is stronger (due to higher ability or higher valuation of the prize) should have a higher ex ante winning probability and expected payoff. The analysis
of Krumer,Megidish, and Sela (2017c) suggests that most results on discrimination in round-robin tournaments with symmetric playerswill also hold with
asymmetricplayers.
7Similardiscouragement effects occur in most forms of dynamic competition (Konrad, 2009, Chapter 8).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT