Are All Private Benefits of Control Ineffective? Principal–Principal Benefits, External Governance Quality, and Firm Performance

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12420
AuthorMarc van Essen,Pursey P. M. A. R. Heugens,Steve Sauerwald,Roxana Turturea
Date01 June 2019
Published date01 June 2019
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Lt d and Society for the Adva ncement of Management Stud ies
Are All Private Benefits of Control Ineffective?
Principal–Principal Benefits, External Governance
Quality, and Firm Performance
Steve Sauerwalda, Pursey P. M. A. R. Heugensb,
Roxana Turtureac and Marc van Essend,e
aUniversity of Ill inois at Chicago; bEras mus University; cAalto Uni versity; dUniversity of South Caroli na;
eEMLYON B usiness School
ABST RACT Private benef its of control (PBC) are benefits t hat controlling shareholders con-
sume, but that are not shared w ith minority shareholders. Research foc using on the value
protection role of corporate governa nce typically frames PBC a s principal–principal ( PP)
agency costs, and i nterpret s them as a form of minority shareholder expropriat ion that
decreases f irm performance. Taking a value creat ion perspect ive of corporate governance,
however, we propose a more nuanced role for PBC. Specif ical ly, we see them also a s PP agency
benefits that c ompensate control ling shareholders for their monitoring and adv isory services,
which can increa se firm performance. Since bot h PP costs and benefits affect f irm perfor-
mance, we theorize t hat PBC enhance firm per formance at a d iminishing rate. Fur thermore,
we show that the effect of PBC on f irm performance is more positive when count ry-level
external govern ance mechanisms are strong.
Keywo rds: control transactions, comparative corporate governance, controlling
shareholders, inst itutions , firm performance, privat e benefits of control
INTRODUCTION
In many parts of the world, controlling shareholders privately enjoy benefits not shared
with minority shareholders (Dharwadk ar et al., 2000; Dyck and Zingales, 2004; Young
et al., 2008). In a narrow interpretation of corporate governance that emphasizes the
value protection role of corporate governance (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997), private ben-
efits of control (PBC ) are overwhelmingly conceived as the result of an agency con flict
Journal of Man agement Studi es 56:4 June 2019
doi: 10.1111 /jom s.12 420
Address for re prints: Steve Sauerwa ld, Department of Manag erial Studies, Univers ity of Illinois at Chica go,
601 South Morgan Str eet, 2210 Univers ity Hall, Chicago, I L 60607-1722, USA (ssauer w@uic.edu).
726 S. Sauerwald et al.
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Lt d and Society for the Adva ncement of Management Stud ies
between controlling and minority shareholders, also cal led the principal–principal (PP)
agency problem (Young et al., 2008). Viewed through this va lue protection lens, PBC
are an expression of PP agency costs t hat reduce shareholder wealth a nd firm profitabil-
ity. Direct PP costs refer to fina ncial r esources controll ing shareholders appropriate that
can no longer be used to advance fi rm performance (Gilson, 2006; Johnson et al., 200 0).
For instance, controlling shareholders may misuse corporate resources by transferring
assets and profits out of f irms via tra nsfer pricing, subsidizing personal loan s, higher
compensation for executive or supervisory roles they perform, perk s such as the use of
corporate jets for personal use, and even outright theft. Ind irect PP costs stem from the
misalig nment between the incentives of control ling owners and those of minority share-
holders. Because controlling shareholders often have a less diversi fied investment port-
folio, they tend to push for less risky strategies in t he firms they control (Gomez-Mejia
et al., 2003; Wright et al., 1996). This may result in the prevention of value-creat ing
takeovers (Li a nd Qian, 2013), and the pursuit of ineffective invest ment decisions (Ward
and Filatotchev, 2010).
While we acknowledge these negative effects of PBC, we also stress a positive side
of PBC that emphasizes a broader value creation perspective of corporate governance
(Filatotchev et al., 2006; Zahra et al., 2009). First, we propose that PBC are the ‘price’
minority shareholders pay for the valuable managerial control and advisory services ren-
dered by the controlling shareholder (Gilson and Schwartz, 2013; Pacces, 2012). These
monitoring and advisory services come at private costs to the controlling shareholder,
such as efforts and under-diversification. Private benefits compensate the controlling
shareholder for these private costs (Enriques et al., 2014). Second, we argue that PBC
provide incentives for the controlling shareholder to engage in entrepreneurial opportu-
nity recognition, a ‘process through which [they] identify meaningful patterns in complex
arrays of events or trends’ (Baron and Ensley, 2006, p. 1331; Shane and Venkataraman,
2000). Controlling shareholders are often invested in multiple companies simultaneously,
and thus may develop opportunity recognition templates that are ‘more clearly defined,
richer in content, and more concerned with factors and conditions related to (…) gener-
ation of positive cash flow’ (Baron and Ensley, 2006, p. 1331; Holderness, 2003; Pacces,
2012). When engaging in this value creation role, controlling shareholders may seek to
extract an amount of PBC that is large enough to serve as an incentive for their oppor-
tunity recognition efforts, but small enough to entail limited consequences for firm per-
formance. After all, when the firms they control perform well, the magnitude and range
of private benefits controlling shareholders can enjoy widens as well. In sum, while PBC
are by definition not shared, PP benefits frequently do have an indirect positive effect on
firm performance. By putting a private premium on control, advice, resource provision,
and opportunity recognition activities, PBC encourage controlling owners to curb man-
agerial opportunism and to initiate and support growth-oriented initiatives, which create
shared benefits for all shareholders by improving firm performance (Zahra et al., 2009).
We do not, however, expect PP costs and benefits to accumulate in equal measure
across the entire PBC spectrum. Specifically, while we expect the relationship between
PBC and firm performance to be positive, we expect performance benefits to accrue with
PBC at a diminishing rate (Gilson and Gordon, 2003). PP benefits tend to accumulate
Are All P rivate Benefits of Control Ineffective? 727
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Lt d and Society for the Adva ncement of Management Stud ies
already in the lower ranges of the PBC spectrum due to the incentives provided to con-
trolling owners. However, in the higher ranges of the spectrum we propose that PP costs
will begin to cancel out PP benefits. Specifically, when PBC become excessively high,
minority shareholders may perceive them as unfair, or disproportionately large com-
pared to the benefits brought to the table by controlling shareholders. This may result
in internal conflicts between minority and controlling shareholders that could negatively
affect firm performance. Even when controlling owners want to pursue entrepreneurial
opportunities, they may have too few resources to realize such opportunities, because
too many resources are converted into PBC. PP costs will therefore materialize predom-
inantly and increasingly in the higher ranges of the PBC spectrum.
Our theory generalizes well, but it is not universal. PBC differ substantially across
countries (Dyck and Zingales, 2004; Nenova, 2003). We direct attention to the quality of
country-level external governance institutions as a potential contingency (Aguilera et al.,
2015; Sauerwald and Peng, 2013). Specifically, we expect that the relationship between
PBC and firm performance will be more positive in countries with strong external cor-
porate governance mechanisms (such as effective rule of law or shareholder protection),
because these mechanisms help protect the wealth of minority shareholders while leav-
ing controlling owners’ incentives to enhance firm performance largely intact (Aguilera
et al., 2008).
An inherent difficulty in measuring PBC is their unobservable nature (Albuquerque
and Schroth, 2010; Burkart et al., 2000; Dyck and Zingales, 2004). Various measurement
approaches exist, centring either on price differentials between voting and non-voting
dual-class stock (Nenova, 2003) or on the premiums paid for control block transactions
(Barclay and Holderness, 1989; Dyck and Zingales, 2004). The block premium strategy,
which builds on the price differentials between the share price for the control block,
and the share price on the stock exchange, is often seen as the preferred method, as it
also applies to firms that did not adopt dual class shares (Nenova, 2003) and to firms
incorporated in countries where dual class shares are illegal (Dyck and Zingales, 2004).
Conceptually, a positive block premium conveys the expectations of the new controlling
owner in terms of how much PBC he or she will be able to extract. The higher the pre-
mium a new owner is willing to pay for gaining control over a firm, the higher the PBC
he or she predicts to extract later on. We therefore opt for the block premium approach
and estimate PBC by compiling a comprehensive sample of up to 962 control transac-
tions, materializing between 1990 and 2016 in 57 countries around the globe.
Our study makes two contributions. First, we introduce the notion of PP benefits
shareholder value created by controlling owners through their provision of shareholder
benefiting services in the areas of control, advice, resource provision, and the implemen-
tation of entrepreneurial opportunities. This concept complements our already robust
understanding of PP costs – which is grounded in the narrow value protecting view of
corporate governance (Li and Qian, 2013; Singla et al., 2014) – with a broader value
creation view of corporate governance (Zahra and Filatotchev, 2004). Under this view,
minority shareholders may be willing to accept a moderate level of PBC in exchange
for the commitment of controlling shareholders. Our study supports the contention that

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT