Approaches to Studying Policy Representation

Date01 February 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12110
Published date01 February 2016
AuthorDavid E. Broockman
DAVID E. BROOCKMAN
Stanford Graduate School of Business
Approaches to Studying Policy
Representation
Some studies of policy representation test hypotheses about the relationship
between citizens’ views and elites’ positions on multiple issues by proceeding one issue
at a time. Others summarize citizens’ and elites’ preferences with “ideology scores” and
test hypotheses with these. I show that approach is flawed. It misinterprets citizens’ ide-
ology scores as summaries of policy preferences, but these scores actually measure
ideological consistency across areas: how often citizens’ ideal policies are liberal or con-
servative. Examples show how attending to this distinction overturns conventional
wisdom: legislators appear similarly moderate as citizens, not more extreme; however,
politically engaged citizens appear especially moderate.
Scholars typically employ one of two approaches when studying
political elites’ representation of public opinion. A f‌irst approach tests a
hypothesis about the relationship between citizens’ opinions and elites’
positions one issue at a time on each of many issues and then examines
how well the hypothesis held across issues. For example, Lax and Phillips
(2012) examine how likely policies are to become law at various levels
of public support. Gilens (2012) compares how likely policies are to
become law depending on levels of public support among those of vari-
ous incomes. And Lenz (2012) examines whether citizens tend to adopt
politicians’views on a variety of issues.
1
A second approach f‌irst computes measures of individual citizens’
and individual politicians’ overall “ideologies” based on their positions
on many policies and tests a hypothesis with these ideology scores. In
such analyses, citizens’ and elites’ policy views are both summarized by
a point on a liberal-conservative index, and their locations on this index
are then compared. For example, in their inf‌luential analysis, Bafumi and
Herron (2010) estimate individual-level “ideal points” for both survey
respondents and their Members of Congress. Bafumi and Herron (2010)
use these estimates to assess correspondence between representatives’
policy decisions and their constituents’ policy preferences, f‌inding that
over 90% of voters are more moderate than legislators but that donors
and primary voters are similarly extreme.
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 41, 1, February 2016 181
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12110
V
C2016 Washington University in St. Louis
Research summarizing voter preferences with ideological scales
has long been conducted (e.g., Enelow and Hinich, 1984) but has
burgeoned in recent years (Barber 2014; Barber
a 2015; Bond and
Messing 2015; Bonica 2013; Caughey 2014; Caughey and Warshaw
2014; Clinton 2006; Ellis and Stimson 2012; Erikson, MacKuen, and
Stimson 2002; Gerber and Lewis 2004; Griff‌in and Newman 2005, 2007;
Masket and Noel 2012; Pan and Xu 2015; Peress 2013; Rogowski and
Tucker 2014; Saiegh 2015; Shor, Berry, and McCarty 2010; Shor 2013;
Stone and Simas 2010; Tausanovitch 2014; Tausanovitch and Warshaw
2014a, 2014b). Expressing a growing sentiment regarding the superiority
of the ideological approach for studying citizens’ policy preferences, Lo,
Proksch, and Gschwend write that “research on elections and party
competition is unthinkable without measures of the ideological positions
of voters” (2014, 205).
This article argues that this ideological approach for studying
voter preferences has crucial and underappreciated f‌laws. The ke y issue
I explore is that ideological scales tend to capture citizens’ degree of
ideological consistency across policy domains (e.g., “this citizen has
liberal views on two-thirds of issues”) but say little about citizens’
views within domains, on issues themselves (e.g., “this citizen supports
state-sponsored healthcare”).
To appreciate this distinction between consistency across domains
and views within domains, consider a common use of ideological scales:
comparing how “extreme” legislators’ policy positions are relative to
citizens’ views. In studies that employ ideological scales for this task,
individual voters’ or politicians’ “extremity” is typically based on the
extremism of their score on an ideological index estimated from
responses to many binary survey items (for citizens) or votes across
many roll calls (for legislators) (e.g., Bafumi and Herron 2010; Barber
2014; Masket and Noel 2012; Peress 2013; Rogowski 2014; Shor 2013).
With this methodology in mind, examine the political preferences and
survey responses given by one voter and one legislator in two issue areas
shown in Table 1. The legislator in Table 1 has consistently conservative
but fairly moderate positions in both issue areas. However, because the
legislator comes down on the conservative side of both issues, the legisla-
tor would appear as conservative as possible on an ideological index
created from these two votes. On the other hand, the voter has extreme
views in both policy areas. Nevertheless, one liberal response and one
conservative response earns her a score at the middle of the index. Literature
on this topic would thus deem the voter moderate despite her thor-
oughly extreme views and the legislator an extremist despite his
moderate positions. But this voter is not really ideologically moderate,
182 David E. Broockman
she is ideologically mixed; and the legislator is not ideologically extreme,
he is ideologically consistent. Interpreting ideological scales as measuring
views on issues themselves rather than ideological consistency can thus
mislead even simple descriptions of individual’s policy preferences.
This distinction has more general consequences for the study of
congruence between voters and their representatives with ideological
scales, questions such as “how well [a politician] represents” his or her
constituency on policy matters (e.g., Bafumi and Herron 2010) or which
constituents a politician represents best (e.g., Griff‌in and Newman 2007;
Tausanovitch 2014).
A second hypothetical illustrates these implications. Suppose you
are a Member of Congress representing a district with f‌ive voters. In the
upcoming session of Congress, you will be asked to cast a roll-call vote
on f‌ive issues. Imagine that, wanting to maintain congruence with district
opinion, you conduct a poll of the f‌ive voters in your district on these
f‌ive issues. The results appear in Table 2. In each cell in Table 2, a 0 cor-
responds to a conservative view on a policy and a 1 corresponds to a
liberal view.
The results of the poll give clear guidance about how to vote
congruently. On each of the f‌ive issues, a majority of your constituents
TABLE 1
Example: Studying Extremism with Ideological Scales
Voter Legislator
Ideal Gay Rights
Policy
Do not allow gays to
teach in public schools
(Extremely conservative)
Civil unions only, no
same-sex marriage
(Moderately conservative)
Answer to survey
question / Roll call
vote: “Should gay
marriage be illegal?”
Yes Yes
Ideal Immigration
Policy
Open borders;
unlimited immigration
(Extremely liberal)
Limit low-skilled immigration
with border protections
(Moderately conservative)
Answer to survey
question / Roll call
vote: “Should
immigration be
restricted?”
No Yes
One-Dimensional
Ideology Estimated
From Survey
Responses / Votes
Moderate Extreme Conservative
183Studying Policy Representation

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT