Applying Econometrics to Assess Market Definition and Market Power

Pages215-263
215
CHAPTER 10
APPLYING ECONOMETRICS TO ASSESS MARKET
DEFINITION AND MARKET POWER
The analyses of market definition and market power are closely
related from both a legal and an econometric standpoint. From a legal
standpoint, evidence on market definition can be informative regarding
market power and vice versa. More directly, analyses of market power
depend on the market definition, with a narrower market definition being
more likely to lead to a finding of market power. From an econometric
standpoint, the same techniques are sometimes used to analyze both
market definition and market power.
This chapter will present the commonly used econometric techniques
for assessing market definition and market power in a legal setting.
A. Legal and Economic Framework
While economists have long discussed the concept of economic
markets and have made frequent reference to “the market,” market
definition from an economic perspective has not always coincided with
the market definition used in antitrust litigation.
1
When economists speak
of markets, what they typically mean is a set of interactions that
encompass all actual and potential customers and suppliers of a product.
In this construct, no bright-line boundaries separate suppliers and buyers
that are “inside” the market from those that are “outside” the market.
To define markets in the context of an antitrust litigation or a merger
review, economists have employed numerous empirical techniques,
2
1
. See, e.g., U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMMN, HORIZONTAL
MERGER GUIDELINES (1992). Recent updates to these guidelines have
erased or downplayed these bright-line tests. See 2010 HORIZONTAL
MERGER GUIDELINES (“Relevant markets need not have precise metes
and bounds”).
2
. Historically, economists have not always paid attention to market
definition. See, e.g., George J. Stigler, The Economists and the Problem
of Monopoly, 72 AM. ECON. REV. 1, Papers and Proceedings of the
Ninety-Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association
216 Econometrics
including SSNIP, critical loss analysis, correlation, co-integration, price
responsiveness, and speed of adjustment. These techniques are generally
aimed at identifying the products and regions that should be included in
the relevant market by analyzing consumer substitution based on sales
and prices data.
Although the markets that have been defined by the courts and in
FTC and DOJ complaints are typically described as if they have sharp
product and geographic boundaries, the empirical tests that economists
employ typically focus on evaluating the degree of substitutability
among products.
3
The economic approach recognizes the difficulty in
delineating bright lines, especially in a market setting where the choices
available to consumers comprise a continuum of products.
4
The tension
between the need to define markets with clear boundaries and the
realities of the marketplace in which the boundaries are not well defined
is one that antitrust economists and attorneys have wrestled with for
years and is an issue that is unlikely to disappear.
5
For this reason,
empirical studies of market definition will continue to be an important
part of any antitrust analysis.
6
(1982) (the “battle on market definitions has received virtually no
attention from us economists.”).
3
. Throughout this chapter, we will refer to goods, products, and services
interchangeably.
4
. Markets where products differ from each other along one or more
dimensions are referred to in th e econo mics literature as having
“differentiated products.”
5
. There is currently debate around the necessity of defining a relevant
market before analyzing market power, as economists have developed
methods for assessin g market power that do not req uire a precisely
defined market. See, e.g., PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP,
ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 913a, at 66 (3d ed. 2007) and J oseph Farrell & Carl
Shapiro, Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Merger s: An Economic
Alternative to Market Definition, 10 B.E. J. THEORETICAL ECON. The
2010 HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES § 4 recognize this while also
indicating that the DOJ and FTC “will normally identify one or more
relevant markets.” See also United States v. H&R Block, Inc., 833 F.
Supp. 2d 36, 84 n.35 (D.D.C. 2011) (“[a]s a legal matter, however, a
market definition may be required by Section 7 of the Clayton Act”).
6
. For example, in 2004 the DOJ and FTC both lost bids to block or enjoin
mergers because they failed to adequately establish the validity of the
“bright line” markets they had defined. See United States v. Oracle Corp.,
Market Definition and Market Power 217
Once the relevant market has been defined, economists can begin to
assess whether any firm or group of firms has market power within that
market.
7
Market power is often measured using market structure (e.g.,
how many firms are in the market and what share of the market each
controls), profit margins, and prices, with the assumption that firms have
more market power (i.e., can increase their prices) if they control a
bigger share of the market and have fewer competitors.
The challenge of measuring the effect of a firm’s exercise of market
power is establishing a causal link between any observed increase in
price or profits and the alleged anticompetitive conduct. To do this
properly requires a reliable assessment of what the price or profits would
have been in the absence of the exercise of market power, and a method
for controlling for other factors that may affect prices or profits. The
central role of econometric analysis in assessing market power lies in its
ability to tackle precisely this challenge.
As discussed in more detail below, many econometric techniques can
be used to isolate the link between anticompetitive conduct and market
outcomes, and thereby help identify the exercise of market power.
B. Market Definition
Defining the relevant market involves delineating the boundaries of
the product and geographic market that will later be used to analyze
market power.
8
Within the boundaries of the relevant market lie the
products and regions among which the relevant demand and supply
forces interact (e.g., the products competing with the product(s) at issue
for consumer demand). Products and regions outside the relevant market
are effectively ignored or treated as a single “all other” category.
Defining the relevant market therefore focuses the analysis of market
power on a specific set of products within a specific set of regions.
From an economic standpoint, defining the product and geographic
market is equivalent to determining which products are substitutes. For
331 F. Supp. 2d 1098 (N.D. Cal. 2004); FTC v. Arch Coal Inc., 329 F.
Supp. 2d 109 (D.D.C. 2004). By contrast, in 2011 the DOJ successfully
blocked the merger of H&R Block and 2SS Holdings based, in part, on
the court’s acceptance o f a precisely d efined market. See United States v.
H&R Block, Inc., 833 F. Supp. 2d 36, 84 n.35 (D.D.C. 2011).
7
. As noted above, it may not always be necessary to define a relevant
market before analyzing market power.
8
. See, e.g., FTC v. CCC Holdings, 605 F. Supp. 2d 26, 37 (D.D.C. 2009).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT