Antitrust made (too) simple

AuthorChristopher R. Leslie
PositionProfessor of Law, University of California Irvine School of Law
Pages917-940
ANTITRUST MADE (TOO) SIMPLE
C
HRISTOPHER
R. L
ESLIE
*
Robert Bork fundamentally changed the field of antitrust law with the pub-
lication of his book The Antitrust Paradox in 1978.
1
The book’s primary
themes were that antitrust doctrine should be concerned only with economic
efficiency (which Bork termed “consumer welfare”) and that antitrust law had
come untethered from efficiency. Bork championed per se legality for a vari-
ety of conduct, including resale price maintenance, non-price vertical re-
straints, and tying arrangements. He advocated greater latitude for horizontal
mergers and complete immunity for all vertical and conglomerate mergers.
Now several decades old, Robert Bork’s The Antitrust Paradox continues
to be among the most influential scholarship in antitrust law.
2
Opinions differ
as to the basis for Bork’s influence. Those who agree with Bork’s description
of antitrust law and his prescriptions on antitrust policy would no doubt argue
that it has been influential because Bork is correct on the merits.
3
Some critics
have suggested that the book’s influence stems from its circular reasoning,
“which is its strength because circular logic is not rebuttable.”
4
This essay
posits an alternative explanation for Bork’s influence: even though Bork was
* Professor of Law, University of California Irvine School of Law. The author thanks Tony
Reese and Su Sun for comments; the organizers of this Bork Symposium—Barak Orbach and
Danny Sokol; and the members of the Advanced Antitrust Working Group at Chicago-Kent
College of Law—Leo Carameli, John Guzzardo, Christopher Haggerty, Jason Hirsh, and
Michael Kasdin.
1
R
OBERT
H. B
ORK
, T
HE
A
NTITRUST
P
ARADOX
: A P
OLICY AT
W
AR WITH
I
TSELF
(rev. ed.
1993).
2
See, e.g., R
UDOLPH
J.R. P
ERITZ
, C
OMPETITION
P
OLICY IN
A
MERICA
: H
ISTORY
, R
HETORIC
,
L
AW
258 (rev. ed. 1996) (referring to The Antitrust Paradox as “probably still the most influen-
tial book about antitrust policy.”); William E. Kovacic, The Antitrust Paradox Revisited: Robert
Bork and the Transformation of Antitrust Policy, 36 W
AYNE
L. R
EV
. 1413, 1417 (1990) (“Since
1890, no single scholarly work has exerted a greater influence than The Antitrust Paradox on the
direction of antitrust policy.”).
3
Another reason that The Antitrust Paradox has been so influential is that Bork had the
ability to implement the ideas espoused in his book as a federal judge for the D.C. Circuit.
4
P
ERITZ
,supra note 2, at 244 (stating that Bork “begins with the assumption that consumers
maximize their welfare and ends with the conclusion that what is chosen [by consumers] maxi-
mizes ‘consumer welfare.’”).
917
918
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 79
largely wrong in his description and analysis of antitrust doctrine, he is influ-
ential because his explanations of complex economic phenomena were so
simple.
This essay examines four issues related to the simplicity of Bork’s ap-
proach to antitrust law. First, it shows how Bork oversimplified the legal land-
scape of antitrust law, which he then used as a foil. Second, it discusses how
Bork made sweeping claims based on weak evidence, oversimplified assump-
tions, and logical fallacies. Third, it hypothesizes why Bork’s views have been
so persuasive to judges. And, fourth, it condemns Bork’s ultimate legacy—his
attempt to thwart the evolution of antitrust economics beyond his basic model
where all markets are efficient and antitrust law is unnecessary. The essay
concludes that the greatest strength of Bork’s scholarship—its simplicity—is
also, ultimately, its greatest weakness.
I. OVERSIMPLIFICATION OF THE LEGAL LANDSCAPE
Bork began his critique of antitrust law with the premise that antitrust doc-
trine was out of control, condemning all manner of business decisions indis-
criminately. To make this claim, Bork exaggerated the landscape of antitrust
law, trying to make it appear more overreaching than it actually was in 1978.
For example, Bork asserted that “vertical mergers are today all but completely
illegal, on the theory that the manufacturer who acquires a retailer also ac-
quires the ability to shut rival manufacturers out of that segment of the mar-
ket.”
5
Bork cites no statistics for his claims because he could not. Far from
being “all but completely illegal,” vertical mergers were common in the years
before the publication of The Antitrust Paradox.
6
In another example of misrepresenting the state of the law, Bork suggested
that requirements contracts were treated as “inherently exclusionary” and
were consequently “dealt with severely.”
7
Through this language, Bork im-
plied that requirements contracts fall perilously close to per se illegality. Yet
requirements contracts were not considered presumptively illegal
8
despite
5
B
ORK
,supra note 1, at 137; see also id. at 225 (“With the passage of the 1950 amendment
to Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the subsequent draconian judicial interpretations, vertical
mergers became, if not illegal per se, almost impossible to defend against government
challenge.”).
6
While the federal antitrust agencies challenged 27 vertical mergers between 1960 and 1970,
they challenged only two purely vertical mergers in the 1970s. David Reiffen & Michael Vita,
Comment: Is There New Thinking on Vertical Mergers?, 63 A
NTITRUST
L.J. 917, 917 (1995)
(citing Alan A. Fisher & Richard Sciacca, An Economic Analysis of Vertical Merger Enforce-
ment Policy, 6 R
ES
. L. & E
CON
. 1, tbl.8 (1984)).
7
B
ORK
,supra note 1, at 137.
8
See Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320, 333 (1961) (“It may well be that
in the context of antitrust legislation protracted requirements contracts are suspect, but they have
not been declared illegal per se.”).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT