Antitrust Law and Distributive Politics in the American States

Published date01 October 2014
Date01 October 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12025
Antitrust Law and Distributive Politics in the
American States
COLIN PROVOST
State enforcement by state attorneys general (AGs) has become a major compo-
nent of American antitrust law. Much has been written about state antitrust
enforcement, but existing accounts of AG incentives and behavior are incomplete.
As elected officials in forty-three states, AGs must represent their constituents
and, therefore, will be drawn to cases that maximize the level of settlement
reward—cases with large, wealthy defendants. I hypothesize and find that state
AGs represent their constituents along ideological lines, but this relationship is
conditioned by case characteristics that involve the potential settlement reward.
Moreover, incentives to participate are likely to be higher when there are clear
violations of the law, as in price-fixing cases, rather than in merger cases, where
no wrongdoing has necessarily been established. The study adds to our under-
standing of antitrust law but also has implications for how distributive politics
shapes political responsiveness to the electorate.
State enforcement of antitrust law has long been an important part of anti-
trust law enforcement in the American federal system. States, through their
attorneys general (AGs), have the power to enforce both state and federal
antitrust laws, and a wealth of research has been published describing this
role of state AGs in antitrust federalism (Lemos 2011; Calkins 2003; First
2001). Some scholars have been highly critical of state antitrust enforcement,
arguing that state AGs are too driven by electoral concerns, rather than by
considerations of economic efficiency, and that their standards diverge from
federal standards, creating a messy, overlapping process (Greve 2005; Posner
2004; Zimmerman 1999; Flexner and Racanelli 1994; Gellhorn 1989). Other
research defends the role of state AGs, claiming that they supply additional
regulation not provided by federal enforcers and that they have better knowl-
edge of local markets (Hubbard and Yoon 2005; Calkins 2003; First 2001).
Valuable as these studies are, little research has demonstrated what drives
AG behavior in antitrust enforcement. As elected officials in forty-three
states, AGs know they must be responsive to their state constituents, as the
The research for this article was supported, in part, by a grant from the British Academy.
Address correspondence to Colin Provost, Department of Political Science/School of Public
Policy, University College London 29/30 Tavistock Square, London, WC1H 9QU, UK.
Telephone: +44 (0)20 7679 4903; E-mail: c.provost@ucl.ac.uk.
bs_bs_banner
LAW & POLICY, Vol. 36, No. 4, October 2014 ISSN 0265–8240
© 2014 The Author
Law & Policy © 2014 The University of Denver/Colorado Seminary
doi: 10.1111/lapo.12025
large majority of them face reelection and many later run for higher office
(Provost 2010a; Mahtesian 1996). However, the level of responsiveness AGs
display toward constituents will vary according to the characteristics of
particular cases they pursue. While some scholars have made strides in ana-
lyzing state antitrust behavior (Lemos 2011; Feinberg and Reynolds 2010),
their research has not fully captured this dynamic of AG accountability
toward the electorate. In this article, I argue that AG responsiveness to the
electorate depends on the role of the state in the lawsuit as well as on the
case’s salience. Salience in turn is represented by defendant characteristics in
antitrust cases.
AGs will strive to be ideologically responsive to their constituents, partly
by bringing home pork in the form of lawsuit settlements. First, they will
target wealthier companies who have the ability to pay large settlements.
The AGs that initiate these lawsuits do so because they tend to come from
liberal states—states where citizens look more favorably upon government
intervention in markets—and also because they have the resources to do
much of the investigative work in such cases. After the case is initiated by
one state or a small group of states, the rest of the states have the option of
joining the settlement. For these remaining states, the decision to join will
also be driven by ideology, as AGs from liberal states will be more willing
to bring antitrust enforcement actions against businesses. However, this
ideological responsiveness on the part of joining states is conditional upon
the salience of the case in question. I define the salience of a case by the
chances it has of being noticed by the broad electorate. The salience of a
case increases along with the monetary stakes in a case. Thus, as defendants
become bigger and wealthier, case salience increases as well and this, in
turn, changes the manner in which AGs are responsive to their constituents.
As defendants grow in wealth, it becomes more difficult for AGs from
conservative states to ignore the potential monetary rewards of participat-
ing in the case. Thus, differences in ideological responsiveness to the elec-
torate ought to gradually disappear, as a majority of the AGs rush to claim
their share of the settlement.
This builds on previous work, which demonstrates that in consumer pro-
tection cases, AGs only exhibit responsiveness to the electorate when defen-
dants are large and wealthy (Provost 2010b). However, in this case, the high
probability of a reward from an antitrust case, particularly against a large,
wealthy defendant, means that AGs from conservative states are more likely
to temporarily put aside conservative principles in order to claim a share of
the reward. Moreover, previous research has not examined the difference
between initiating and joining such litigation, but in this analysis, I examine
the factors that drive states to initiate, as well as join, multistate lawsuits.
Examining the types of antitrust infractions AGs are most likely to pursue
has been done in previous research (e.g., Feinberg and Reynolds 2010) but
also without explanation of why particular types of cases see greater AG
participation.
Provost ANTITRUST LAW AND DISTRIBUTIVE POLITICS 409
© 2014 The Author
Law & Policy © 2014 The University of Denver/Colorado Seminary

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT