Antitrust by analogy: developing rules for loyalty rebates and bundled discounts

AuthorSean P. Gates
PositionMember of the California Bar
Pages99-137
ANTITRUST BY ANALOGY: DEVELOPING RULES FOR
LOYALTY REBATES AND BUNDLED DISCOUNTS
S
EAN
P. G
ATES
*
Though analogy is often misleading, it is the least misleading thing we have.
—Samuel Butler
Economics has come to dominate antitrust jurisprudence. Preserving and
enhancing economic welfare (in one form or another) is now the conceded
goal of antitrust. Accordingly, economic analysis permeates antitrust scholar-
ship, drives agency decisions, and is the basis of modern judicial decisions.
The thought of developing an antitrust liability rule without a well-considered
underlying economic theory is anathema. The mention of such a possibility
brings pursed lips, condescending looks, and hushed ridicule. But what should
a court do when there is no consensus on the underlying economic theory?
That is the situation for the antitrust treatment of loyalty rebates and bundled
discounts.
The antitrust case law offers little guidance. Many of the critical debates in
antitrust law have centered on whether the prevailing framework of analysis
for particular competitive conduct should be changed in light of economic
analyses. In Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.,
1
for instance, the
Supreme Court was asked to revisit its prior holding that vertical nonprice
restraints were “so obviously destructive of competition” as to merit per se
condemnation.
2
This holding had become “the subject of continuing contro-
versy and confusion, both in the scholarly journals and in the federal courts.”
3
As the Court acknowledged, the “great weight of scholarly opinion [was] . . .
critical of the decision” and lower courts had sought to limit the holding.
4
Concluding that its prior holding rested on “formalistic line drawing” rather
than economic effects, the Court overruled its prior decision, rejected the use
* Member of the California Bar.
1
433 U.S. 36 (1977).
2
United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365, 379 (1967).
3
Continental T.V., 433 U.S. at 47.
4
Id. at 48 nn.13 & 14.
99
100
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 79
of per se analysis for vertical non-price restrictions, and held that the rule of
reason should apply instead.
5
Similarly, the Court has used developments in economic theory to reject
established antitrust precedents. For example, in State Oil Co. v. Khan,
6
the
Court overruled its nearly 30-year-old holding in Albrecht v. Herald Co.
7
that
vertical maximum price fixing is per se illegal. After chronicling the develop-
ment of the antitrust treatment of vertical restraints, the Court concluded “that
there is insufficient economic justification for per se invalidation of vertical
maximum price fixing.”
8
In Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc.,
9
the Court rejected the
decades-old rule in tying cases that “when a seller conditions its sale of a
patented product (the ‘tying’ product) on the purchase of a second product
(the ‘tied’ product),” the seller should be presumed to possess market power
in the market for the patented product.
10
Noting that the “vast majority of
academic literature recognizes that a patent does not necessarily confer market
power,”
11
the Court abrogated its prior cases by holding that “in all cases
involving a tying arrangement, the plaintiff must prove that the defendant has
market power in the tying product.”
12
Finally, in Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
13
the Court
overruled the nearly century-old rule that minimum resale price maintenance
is per se unlawful. The Court found that the bases for the rule, first announced
in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co.
14
—the common-law
rule against restraints on alienation and treating vertical restraints as analo-
gous to horizontal restraints—had been rejected in the Court’s more recent
antitrust cases.
15
Noting that “respected authorities in the economics literature
suggest the per se rule is inappropriate, and there is now widespread agree-
5
Id. at 58–59.
6
522 U.S. 3 (1997).
7
390 U.S. 145 (1968).
8
State Oil, 522 U.S. at 18; see also 522 U.S. at 14–15 (citing Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA
Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 343 n.13 (1990) (“The procompetitive potential of a vertical maxi-
mum price restraint is more evident now than it was when Albrecht was decided . . . . Many
commentators have identified procompetitive effects of vertical, maximum price fixing.” (cita-
tions omitted)); see also Khan v. State Oil Co., 93 F.3d 1358, 1363 (7th Cir. 1996) (following
Albrecht “despite all its infirmities, its increasingly wobbly, moth-eaten foundations”).
9
547 U.S 28 (2006).
10
Id. at 31.
11
Id. at 44.
12
Id. at 46.
13
551 U.S. 877 (2007).
14
220 U.S. 373 (1911).
15
Leegin, 551 U.S. at 887–88.
2013]
A
NTITRUST BY
A
NALOGY
101
ment that resale price maintenance can have procompetitive effects,”
16
the
Court overruled Dr. Miles and held that “[v]ertical price restraints are to be
judged according to the rule of reason.”
17
But what if there is no established framework of analysis, no long line of
cases, no “great weight of scholarly opinion” presenting a consensus view?
What if there is no standard underlying economic analysis of the particular
conduct?
That is precisely the situation with the antitrust treatment of rebates (loyalty
and bundled).
18
The scholarship is divided.
19
The economics is murky.
20
The
courts are just starting to address such conduct. The critical question then is
what tool can the courts use to develop antitrust liability rules for rebates?
16
Id. at 900.
17
Id. at 907.
18
Recognizing the differences, I use the term “rebates” to refer to both loyalty rebates (rebates
given when the customer meets certain purchasing thresholds, typically a percentage of its re-
quirements) and bundled discounts (discounts or rebates given when the customer purchases two
products together or more typically meets certain purchasing thresholds based on its require-
ments for a bundle of products, e.g., 90% of the customer’s requirements for a certain class of
pharmaceuticals).
19
Compare Thomas A. Lambert, Appropriate Liability Rules for Tying and Bundled Dis-
counting, 72 O
HIO
S
T
. L.J. 909, 980–81 (2011) (arguing for cost-based test similar to predatory
pricing), and Herbert Hovenkamp & Erik Hovenkamp, Complex Bundled Discounts and Anti-
trust Policy, 57 B
UFF
. L. R
EV
. 1227, 1234–37 (2009) (advocating version of cost-based test),
with Kevin W. Caves & Hal J. Singer, Bundles in the Pharmaceutical Industry: A Case Study of
Pediatric Vaccines 48 (Aug. 11, 2011), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1908306 (arguing
that “[r]ecent scholarship demonstrates that cost-based tests . . . may fail to properly classify a
given bundled pricing scheme as anticompetitive”), Einer Elhauge, Tying, Bundled Discounts,
and the Death of the Single Monopoly Profit Theory, 123 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 397, 461–69 (2009)
(arguing against use of price-cost tests for bundled discounts) [hereinafter Elhauge, Bundled
Discounts], Einer Elhauge, How Loyalty Discounts Can Perversely Discourage Discounting, 5 J.
C
OMPETITION
L. & E
CON
. 189, 216–17 (2009) (arguing against price-cost tests for loyalty dis-
counts) [hereinafter Elhauge, Loyalty Discounts], and Timothy J. Brennan, Bundled Rebates as
Exclusion Rather than Predation, 4 J. C
OMPETITION
L. & E
CON
. 335, 337–38 (2008) (arguing
that cost-based test is flawed).
20
See, e.g., Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae at 12 n.9, 3M Co. v. LePage’s Inc.,
No. 02-1865 (U.S. May 28, 2004), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/f203900/
203900.pdf (“the theoretical and empirical analysis of [bundled rebates] as a potentially exclu-
sionary mechanism is relatively recent and sparse”); Nicholas Economides, Loyalty/Requirement
Rebates and the Antitrust Modernization Commission: What Is the Appropriate Liability Stan-
dard?, 54 A
NTITRUST
B
ULL
. 259, 259 (2009) (noting a “number of alternative economic stan-
dards have been proposed for establishing antitrust liability” in rebate cases); Einer Elhauge &
Abraham L. Wickelgren, Anti-competitive Market Division Through Loyalty Discounts Without
Buyer Commitment, Harvard John M. Olin Discussion Paper No. 723 (Aug. 2012) (noting divi-
sion among scholarship); Bruce H. Kobayashi, Does Economics Provide a Reliable Guide to
Regulating Commodity Bundling by Firms? A Survey of the Economic Literature, 1 J. C
OMPETI-
TION
L. & E
CON
. 707 (2005) (concluding that the economic literature does not support whether
the exclusionary effects of bundled discounts outweigh procompetitive benefits); Timothy J.
Muris & Vernon L. Smith, Antitrust and Bundled Discounts: An Experimental Analysis, 75 A
NTI-
TRUST
L.J. 399, 400 (2008) (noting lack of consensus regarding antitrust standard for bundled
discounts).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT