Antitrust and Financial Regulation in the Wake of Philadelphia National Bank: Complements, Not Substitutes

AuthorLawrence J. White
PositionStern School of Business, New York University
Pages413-430
ANTITRUST AND FINANCIAL REGULATION IN THE
WAKE OF PHILADELPHIA NATIONAL BANK:
COMPLEMENTS, NOT SUBSTITUTES
L
AWRENCE
J. W
HITE
*
Antitrust and the financial sector have had a wary relationship with each
other.
1
Because the financial sector traditionally has been and continues to be
heavily regulated, incumbent firms in that sector have often preferred to be
shielded from antitrust scrutiny by claiming (usually with the support of their
regulators) that financial regulation was sufficient to protect the public interest
and consequently that antitrust jurisdiction was not necessary. This appears to
have been one of the arguments advanced by the appellees (but rejected by the
Supreme Court) in Philadelphia National Bank.
2
Although this shielding has
diminished over the decades, a prominent modern remnant of that tradition is
the continued exclusion of insurance companies (which are regulated by the
states) from federal antitrust jurisdiction by the McCarran-Ferguson Act of
1945.
3
This article will explore the connections between the financial sector and
antitrust. It will argue that the competition paradigm that serves as the founda-
tion for antitrust is as valid for the financial sector as it is for the other sectors
of the economy where antitrust regularly applies. Accordingly, there should
* Stern School of Business, New York University. During 1982–1983, the author was the
Director of the Economic Policy Office of the U.S. Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division.
During 1986–1989, the author was a board member on the Federal Home Loan Bank Board with
responsibilities that included being a board member of Freddie Mac. An earlier version of this
article was presented at the Conference on the Fiftieth Anniversary of United States v. Philadel-
phia National Bank held at New York University School of Law (Nov. 15, 2013). Thanks are
due to the participants at the Conference for helpful comments.
1
For an earlier discussion of this wariness, see Lawrence J. White, Financial Regulation and
the Current Crisis: A Guide for Antitrust, in C
OMPETITION AS
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
65 (Bernard A.
Nigro, Maureen K. Ohlhausen & Charles T. Compton eds., 2010).
2
United States v. Phila. Nat’l Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 368 (1963).
3
McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–1015; see also Credit Suisse Secs. (USA)
L.L.C. v. Billing, 551 U.S. 264 (2007) (The Supreme Court decided that the Securities and
Exchange Commission’s regulation of securities underwriting for initial public offerings (IPOs)
precluded an antitrust case against the underwriters.).
413
414
A
NTITRUST
L
AW
J
OURNAL
[Vol. 80
be no exemptions from antitrust scrutiny for the firms that are in and around
the financial sector. However, the financial sector is an area where firms that
compete with each other often find it convenient—and efficient—also to
communicate and cooperate with each other; but such communication and
cooperation also raise all of the usual suspicions as to the opportunities for
anticompetitive (and thus socially inefficient) collusion with respect to prices
or other important dimensions of competition. This communication and coop-
eration among competitors in the financial context thus raise important anti-
trust issues that deserve more discussion and analysis.
This article will proceed as follows: Part I will lay out some important
background concepts with respect to finance, the financial sector, and finan-
cial regulation. Part II will address some specific areas of finance where vig-
orous antitrust enforcement—public and private —has been present and is
appropriate. Section III will discuss some specific issues that arise in the areas
where financial firms that compete with each other may also communicate
and cooperate with each other. Section IV will conclude.
I. FINANCE AND FINANCIAL REGULATION
Finance is special for at least three reasons: First, finance is ubiquitous.
Almost all enterprises need finance to obtain the resources for investments
and to bridge the gap between the time when inputs are paid and the time
when payment is received for the sale of outputs. Almost all governments
need finance, again, to obtain the resources for investments and to bridge the
gap between the time that expenditures are made and the time when tax reve-
nues are received. Almost all individuals need finance, so as to accommodate
large investments and purchases and to bridge smaller expenditure/income
gaps. In addition, finance underlies the operation of the monetary/payments
system of any modern economy.
Second, finance unavoidably involves a time dimension: A loan or an in-
vestment is made at an initial point in time;
4
repayment is expected to occur at
some future point in time.
5
This time interval means that the lender always
faces some uncertainty as to whether the borrower will repay the loan. This
uncertainty reflects the lender’s informational disadvantage vis-`a-vis the bor-
rower (i.e., asymmetric information). Before the loan is made, the lender may
have difficulty in figuring out whether a prospective borrower is likely to
4
For ease of exposition, the following discussion will be in terms of a “loan” that has a
“lender” and a “borrower”; but the basic ideas carry over to the issues that surround equity
investing.
5
For insurance, there is a similar time sequence: At an initial point in time a commitment to
insure against a specific event is made, and the insured party makes a “premium” payment to the
insurer; then, subsequently, if the insured-against event occurs, the insurance payment is made
by the insurer back to the insured party.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT