Anchoring and Probability Weighting in Option Prices

Published date01 June 2017
AuthorAndy Fodor,Dean Diavatopoulos,Kevin Krieger,R. Jared DeLisle
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21833
Date01 June 2017
Anchoring and Probability Weighting
in Option Prices
R. Jared DeLisle,* Dean Diavatopoulos, Andy Fodor and Kevin Krieger
Cumulative prospect theory argues that the human decision-making process tends to
improperly weight unlikely events. Another behavioral phenomenon, anchoring bias, is the
failure to update beliefs away from established anchor points. In this study, we nd evidence
that equity option market investors both anchor to prices and incorporate a probability
weighting function similar to that proposed by cumulative prospect theory. The biases result in
inefcient prices for put options when rms have relatively high or relatively low implied
volatilities. This has implications for the cost of hedging long portfolios and long individual
equity positions. © 2017 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 37:614638, 2017
1. INTRODUCTION
Many nancial studies use aspects of behavioral theories to examine phenomena observed in
equity markets.
1
In this study, we employ two well-documented behavioral theories to explain
the underperformance of put options with very low and very high implied volatilities relative
to other put options with the same moneyness and maturities. We nd evidence that equity
option investors anchor to prices (or implied volatilities) and incorporate a probability
weighting function similar to that proposed by cumulative prospect theory (CPT). CPT
(Tversky & Kahneman, 1992), unlike standard utility theory, argues that the human decision-
making process depends on relative gains and losses, not nal wealth, as losses impact utility
more negatively than gains of the same magnitude increase utility. The asymmetry of an
R. Jared DeLisle is at the Department of Economics and Finance, Jon M. Huntsman School of Business, Utah
State University, Logan, Utah. Dean Diavatopoulos is at Department of Finance, Albers School of Business
and Economics, Seattle University, Seattle, Washington. Andy Fodor is at Department of Finance, College of
Business, Ohio University, Athens, Ohio. Kevin Krieger is at Department of Accounting and Finance,
University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida. We thank the editor (Robert Webb) for his insightful
suggestions. We are grateful for the valuable comments from the participants of the 2015 Financial
Management Association meeting, 2016 Derivatives Markets Conference, and the 2016 Annual Conference
of the Asia-Pacic Association of Derivatives.
JEL Classication: G1, G13
*Correspondence author, Utah State University, Department of Economics and Finance, Jon M. Huntsman School
of Business, 3565 Old Main Hill, Logan, UT 84322-3565. Tel: 435-797-0885, Fax: 435-797-2701,
email: jared.delisle@usu.edu
Received November 2016; Accepted November 2016
1
Prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979), cumulative prospect theory (Tversky & Kahneman, 1992), mental
accounting (Henderson & Peterson, 1992; Shefrin & Thaler, 1988; Thaler, 1980, 1985), and heuristics (Kahneman
& Tversky, 1972; Tversky & Kahneman, 1974) have been successfully applied to many stylized facts in nancial
markets that are difcult to explain in a standard rational efcient markets framework (e.g., Fama, 1965, 1970;
Friedman, 1953; Markowitz, 1952a,b).
The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 37, No. 6, 614638 (2017)
© 2017 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online 2 February 2017 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21833
individuals utility due to gains versus losses is referred to as loss aversion. Tversky and
Kahneman also contend humans are poor at internalizing event probabilities and appear to
use a unique weighting function to convert an actual probability into a perceived probability
which assigns a high value to low probability events, resulting in overly risk averse or risk-
seeking behavior, depending upon whether the outcome of the event is a loss or a gain.
Anchoring is a documented psychological bias that is independent of CPT, but it is required
by CPT to determine a reference point that denes regions of gains and losses.
In addition, the literature over the past two decades presents considerable evidence that
investors use anchor points in their investing decisions. Kahneman, Slovic, and Tversky
(1982) dene anchoring as the process of making adjustments away from a reference point
(the anchor) where the adjustments are biased toward this reference point. The anchor point
may come from the problem at hand (Kahneman et al., 1982) or even a random value such as
the last two digits of a Social Security Number (Ariely, Loewenstein, & Prelec, 2003).
Kahneman et al. (1982) and Kahneman (1992) survey studies providing evidence of
anchoring by individuals. Using laboratory experiments, Myagkov and Plott (1997) and
Marsat and Williams (2013) also nd support for the usage of anchor points. Benartzi and
Thaler (1995) contend that investors use a reference stock price, that is, the current price, as
an anchor point and determine, consistent with loss aversion, that investors weigh a loss
about twice as much as a similar gain.
Supporting this assertion, George and Hwang (2004) identify an investing strategy that
utilizes an anchor point of a stocks 52-week high price that bests Jegadeesh and Titmans
(1993) simple momentum strategy. The 52-week high price should not contain any
information about a stocks future value in a weak-form efcient market. Yet, the evidence
George and Hwang presents suggest investors anchor to the 52-week high and are reluctant
to value the stock price above that price, even if a higher price is well justied. Bhootra and
Hur (2013) strengthen the anchoring argument by demonstrating an increase in the
protability of George and Hwangs strategy by conditioning on the timing of the 52-week
high anchor point, which is consistent with Grinblatt and Hans (2005) theoretical model
where the purchase price of the stock serves as the investors anchor point.
2
Similarly, Baker,
Pan, and Wurgler (2012) nd managers use price anchors in determining premiums paid in
mergers and acquisitions.
In addition to looking for evidence of anchoring, we also investigate the tendency of
individuals to improperly weight low-probability events. In general, humans tend to do a poor
job of internalizing probabilities. A series of studies by Teigen (1974a,b, 1983) shows that an
individuals sum of interpreted probabilities of a set of outcomes often exceeds one.
Kahneman and Tversky (1984) and Tversky and Kahneman (1992), show that, under CPT,
individuals overweight (underweight) small (moderate or high) probabilities. Figure 1 shows
a graphical example of their ndings. The perceived probability of an event, p(P), is much
higher than the actual probability, P, when Pis low. Thus, when individuals apply such a
weighting function to observed probabilities, it gives rise to extremely risk averse (seeking)
behavior when dealing with highly improbable losses (gains) as the value of each outcome is
multiplied not by an additive probability, but by a decision weight.
Another implication of a weighting function is that individuals evaluate a risk of 1 in
100,000 similarly as 1 in 10,000,000. Kunreuther, Novemsky, and Kahneman (2001)
empirically conrm such a notion. The regime of extremely small probabilities is unstable,
where the risks are either grossly overweighted or ignored (e.g., rounded down to zero).
2
In the context of Grinblatt and Hans model, the concept of an anchor is important with respect to loss aversion
because individuals use it as a xed reference to determine if selling an asset (i.e., the capital gains overhang)
provides pain in the form of a loss or pleasure in the form of a gain.
Anchoring, Probability Weighting, and Options 615

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT