An Institutional Configurational Approach to Cross‐National Diversity in Corporate Governance

AuthorRuth V. Aguilera,Ilir Haxhi
Date01 May 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12247
Published date01 May 2017
An Institutional Configurational Approach to
Cross-National Diversity in Corporate Governance
Ilir Haxhi and Ruth V. Aguilera
Amsterdam Business School, University of Amsterdam; Northeastern University and ESADE Business
School, Universitat Ramon Llull
ABSTRACT Corporate governance (CG) research has typically been studied from rather
disparate disciplinary approaches, thereby offering myopic and often conflicting rationales. We
develop an institutional configurational approach to integrate this ‘siloed’ field and explain
CG patterns around the world. To do so, we draw on an inductive, theory-building
methodology based on fuzzy-set logic to uncover the configurations across institutional actor-
centred domains and their impact on CG patterns. Empirically, we explore the necessary and
sufficient causal conditions leading to different features of codes of good governance across 32
OECD countries. We generate propositions linking configurational institutional domains to
code features. Our results show that a single institutional domain by itself is not sufficient to
explain CG outcomes, and that these domains need to be considered in conjunction, leading,
in turn, to the identification of four distinct configurational governance prototypes. Our study
offers a comprehensive account of drivers of cross-national differences in CG and yields useful
insights for managing and regulating governance.
Keywords: codes, corporate governance, institutional configuration, qualitative comparative
analysis
INTRODUCTION
In recent years, much of the comparative management literature has striven to explain
how national varieties of capitalism impact firm behaviour and managerial practices
across advanced industrial countries. A core characteristic of these frameworks is their
focus on institutional diversity and how it shapes firms’ organizational and strategic
behaviour (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Whitley, 1992). For example, national financial insti-
tutions such as capital markets and banks account for the long versus short-term firm
orientation (Connelly et al., 2010). Managers also capitalize on institutional diversity –
Address for reprints: Ilir Haxhi, International Management & Strategy Section, Amsterdam Business School,
University of Amsterdam, P.O. Box 15953, 1001 NL Amsterdam, The Netherlands (i.haxhi@uva.nl).
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd and Society for the Advancement of Management Studies
Journal of Management Studies 54:3 May 2017
doi: 10.1111/joms.12247
for instance when they become aware of how different national institutions and their
varieties of business organization contribute to multiple types of pay structures or
employment security (Filatotchev and Wright, 2011). As noted by both Scott (1995) and
North (1991), institutions are not only regulatory schemes but are also often adopted as
normative and cognitive collective norms of conduct. In turn, organizations are embed-
ded in these sets of institutions that jointly make up the Gestalt types of Capitalism in
which organizations and managers operate (Jackson and Deeg, 2006). Thus, under-
standing the composition of these varieties of Capitalism sheds critical light on how firms
and managers can more effectively develop and sustain competitive advantage.
Corporate Governance (CG) systems are the result of the combination of these insti-
tutions, forming different types of Capitalism. Because they are directly linked to firm
strategies and outcomes, scholars anchored in multiple disciplines have explored differ-
ences in cross-national CG systems, typically focusing on the influence of one institution
on CG patterns. Unfortunately, this combined research yields a field that is fragmented
along disciplinary lines (Aguilera and Jackson, 2010). For instance, to explain the sources
of cross-national CG variation, law and economics scholars point to differing protection
of capital rights (La Porta et al., 1998; Shleifer and Vishny, 1997), political economists
refer to the role of political coalitions within the State (Cioffi, 2010; Gourevitch and
Shinn, 2005), and industrial relations and managerial scholars focus on power relations
within firms (Davis, 2009; O’Sullivan, 2000).
This research fragmentation has impaired our full understanding of the complexity of
CG patterns in the way they emerge, evolve and diffuse around the world for two main
reasons. First, institutions do not work in isolation but rather are part of a broader
national institutional system (Amable, 2003). Thus, CG patterns are affected by multi-
ple, functionally interrelated sets of institutions resulting in configurations of institutions.
These institutional configurations are more complex than the traditional dichotomous
model of CG – the shareholder versus stakeholder model –, which has dominated the
comparative CG literature (Aguilera and Jackson, 2010). Second, the emphasis on the
structural attributes of institutions, such as the strength of labour union rights, overlooks
the interests that specific agents (for instance, investors or governments) play in reacting
to, and shaping, these institutions (Giddens, 1984; Greenwood et al., 2011). As stated by
Aoki, ‘in order to really understand why a particular institution emerges in a domain of
one economy but not in a similar domain of another economy, we need to make explicit
the mechanism of interdependencies among institutions across domains in each econ-
omy’ (2001, p. 18).
Most importantly, this single institutional focus might introduce a biased view of gov-
ernance in the comparative management literature. For instance, a one-dimensional
focus on capital rights (La Porta et al., 1998) neglects the salience of power relations
between labour and management, since managers are directly affected by capital own-
ers, whereas employees can influence managers through interest group coalitions (Gour-
evitch and Shinn, 2005). Similarly, although legal scholars tend to assume that hard law
is the most effective means to institutionalize norms (Coffee, 1999), institutional sociolo-
gists argue that soft law is the one that becomes truly internalized and subsequently insti-
tutionalized (Aguilera et al., 2015). As a last example, while Aguilera and Cuervo-
Cazurra (2004) claim that Civil Law typically triggers the diffusion of codes as a
262 I. Haxhi and R. V. Aguilera
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd and Society for the Advancement of Management Studies
response to weak protection of investors, Haxhi and van Ees (2010) show that codes gen-
erally amply develop in Common Law countries with stronger capital rights protection.
To explore these complex institutional interactions, and help clarify biased and/or
conflicting CG findings, we steer away from the prevailing idea of stressing an individual
institution in the analysis of CG patterns. Instead, we draw on an all-inclusive configura-
tional approach that emphasizes the importance of systemic institutional interactions in
the broader CG system. Our goal is thus to answer: Why and how do key institutions influence
cross-national patterns of CG practices?
We employ an inductive, theory-building research design and build on three related
theoretical perspectives: Actor-Centered Institutionalism (Aguilera and Jackson, 2003),
Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) (Hall and Soskice, 2001) and National Business System
(NBS) (Whitley, 1992), to compare how institutional diversity impacts organizational
outcomes across advanced economies. While these perspectives are in themselves useful,
they do not explicitly account for the interactions across institutional domains, given
that their respective one-dimensional logic neglects the complexity and embeddedness
of institutions (Amable, 2003). These complementarities are also essential to uncover the
different properties of CG systems. We purposefully develop an institutional configura-
tional framework that highlights the interactions of institutional domains (i.e., Capital,
Management-Labour, and the State), and includes most of the institutional arrange-
ments defining economic organization and CG practices. We contend that institutional
domains vary across countries both in how they are individually composed and in how
their corresponding actors interact with one another, and the effect on decision-making
and control over the process of creating CG practices. In sum, we seek to move beyond
the current silo-based discussions and underscore systemic institutional interactions
within the broader CG system.
For the analysis of CG practices, we focus on a central and widespread practice: codes
of good governance (hereafter ‘codes’). In contrast to the somewhat abstract operation-
alization of CG, codes are the observable instrument through which national CG is
adopted. This makes codes a tangible outcome as well as an appropriate level of analysis
to disentangle broader debates around comparative CG. Codes are instruments of self-
regulation, delineating best practices with respect to boards, management, supervision,
disclosure, and auditing (Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazurra, 2004). They have key implica-
tions for a variety of actors in their respective institutional domains, including managers,
owners, regulators, and most firm stakeholders. Codes are the product of the diversity in
the institutions because their development is contingent on the configurational relation-
ships between country-level institutional domains. In other words, cross-national com-
parisons of CG systems can be best achieved through the empirical analysis of the CG
codes adopted in different countries. Moreover, codes matter for national and firm gov-
ernance competitiveness because they equip firms with the necessary governance prac-
tices to win investors trust – although for some firms, codes can also demand redundant
or costly practices at the risk of over-governance (Aguilera et al., 2008). Finally, our
arguments about codes are easily applicable to other management practices such as ISO
quality settings, HR standards, and sustainability practices.
We use a Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) approach based on the logic of
the fuzzy sets (fs/QCA) technique (Crilly, 2011; Fiss, 2007; Ragin, 2000) to explore the
263An Institutional Configurational Approach in Corporate Governance
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd and Society for the Advancement of Management Studies

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT