An Economic Analysis of Matsushita

AuthorRoger D. Blair,Richard E. Romano,James M. Fesmire
DOI10.1177/0003603X9103600203
Published date01 June 1991
Date01 June 1991
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Summer 1991
An economic analysis
of
Matsushita
BY ROGER D. BLAIR,* JAMES M. FESMIRE,**
and RICHARD E. ROMANO***
1. Introduction
355
The Supreme Court's Matsushita decision! continued the trend
toward greater economic sophistication in judicial reasoning.>
This litigation involved a complaint about predatory pricing in
* Huber Hurst Professor of Business and Legal Studies, College of
Business Administration, University of Florida, Gainesville.
** Professor of Economics, University of Tampa.
***
Associate
Professor
of
Economics,
University
of
Florida,
Gainesville.
AUTHORS' NOTE: We thank the College
of
Business Administration
of
the University
of
Florida
for
financial support. Our colleagues. Elias
Dinopoulos
and Jon Hamilton,
and
an anonymous referee
provided
useful comments, but cannot be blamedfor what follows.
Matsushita Electric Industrial Co., Ltd. v. Zenith Radio Corpora-
tion, 106 S. Ct. 1348 (1986).
2This greater sophistication can be traced at least to the Court's
decision in Continental TV v. GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. 36 (1977), which
recognized the value of vertical restraints that faciitate interbrand compe-
tition at the expense of intrabrand competition.
C 1991by Fcdcrol Legal Publlcaticns, Inc.
356 : The antitrust bulletin
the U.S. consumer electronics market that allegedly spanned two
decades. Finding that the alleged predation was not a reasonable
economic inference given the facts presented, the Supreme Court
affirmed alower court's decision to dismiss the complaint of
Zenith
and NUE on a motion for summary judgment."
This
decision leaves us in the dark as to what actually happened since
neither the Court nor the litigants provided much in the way of
an alternative explanation. In its place, we offer three alternative
and more plausible explanations than predation, and examine
arguments
that
Zenith
and NUE
might
have
made
on
their
behalf. Although we agree with the
Court's
rejection
of
the
predatory pricing allegation, whether or not the outcome was
appropriate is less clear.
Initially, we provide some background on the Matsushita
litigation: the allegations and facts, the decision, its procedural
significance, and the questions it raises. Next, in light of the facts
and allegations, we analyze several alternative explanations for
the behavior of the Japanese producers, drawing our own conclu-
sions as to what transpired in this market. Finally, we consider
the normative implications of
our
conclusions and add some
closing remarks.
II.
The
Matsushita litigation
Zenith and NUE complained that 21 Japanese manufacturers
of consumer electronics products began conspiring to monopo-
lize the U.S. market as early as 1953. It alleged that the Japanese
producers violated sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, section
2(a) of the Robinson-Patman Act, and section 73 of the Wilson
Tariff Act. The core of the complaint was simple: the Japanese
consumer electronics industry was a cooperative oligopoly that
conspired to raise prices in Japan and thereby earn excess profits
Summary judgment is a procedural means of disposing of a case
without atrial.
If
the court finds that there is no genuine issue of
material fact, then the defendant is entitled to a judgment in its favor as
a matter of law.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT