AN ALTERNATIVE THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK FOR ECONOMICS.

AuthorKohn, Meir

As a profession, economics is thriving. The number of economists is large and growing. The volume of their output is exploding--more articles are published each year in a growing number of journals. As a science, however, economics is not doing so well. The questions addressed by all those articles seem to be getting smaller and smaller. And there seems to be little or no progress on the big questions of economics such as economic development and growth, economic fluctuations, and the proper role of government in tire economy. Most of the articles published are econometric, and the results of many are of questionable quality.

These problems of economics are, however, far from unique. There has been much talk in recent years of a general crisis of science. Despite ever more resources devoted to scientific research, the pace of scientific progress has slowed markedly. And the problems with statistical work in economics are part of a much broader "replicability crisis" in statistical work in general.

A major underlying cause of the general crisis of science is bureaucratization. Since World War II, scientific research has increasingly become concentrated in universities, and universities have become increasingly bureaucratized. Academic advancement has come to depend on metrics such as the number of publications in leading journals and the number of citations. Judging the significance of work is rarely even attempted: "deans can't read, but they can count." Incentives matter, and these bureaucratic incentives promote low-risk, low-value research. Bureaucratization is tire result, in turn, of two related developments-the increasing adoption by universities of the model of the German research university, and the growing role of government in funding scientific research.

While economics shares with science in general the underlying cause of its problems, there is a specific factor in economics that has exacerbated these problems significantly-namely, a major wrong turn in economic theory. I will begin by describing the nature of this wrong turn, and then consider why it has been accepted so readily and why, indeed, it is a wrong turn. I will then discuss how economics has responded to the problems created by the wrong turn in theory and why that response has been inadequate. I will argue that the only real solution is to adopt a different theoretical framework. I will then describe, very briefly, a theory I have been developing and explain why this offers a better theoretical framework for economics as a whole. I will conclude by considering how economists might be persuaded to adopt this alternative framework.

The Wrong Turn in Economic Theory

In the period immediately after World War II, there was a transformation in the nature of economic theory-a change both in substance and in method. This transformation has its origins in the work of two great economists-Paul Samuelson and John Hicks. (1) Samuelson wished to reformulate economic theory in tire language of mathematics. He believed that doing so would promote greater clarity and precision, and he hoped that mathematization would lead to a formal unification of the whole of economic theory. While Samuelson's goal was formal unification, Hicks's goal was substantive unification. Hicks believed that much of economics could be understood in terms of the theory of value-the part of economics that seeks to explain the pattern of relative prices in an economy and the resulting allocation of resources.

Samuelson's goals and Hicks's proved highly complementary. The theory of value lends itself to mathematization. Hence, reducing economics to value theory offered a promising route to a more general mathematization of economics. The resulting mathematical model of value theory rapidly came to dominate economic theory. Indeed, for most economists, it became economic theory; this is the theory taught in today's economics textbooks. I will refer to it in what follows as "the conventional theory." (2)

The conventional theory came to dominate so quickly and so easily, because it met the needs of bureaucratic science. Mathematical modeling is technically difficult, but easy to grade. Moreover, it requires little or no acquaintance with actual economies-speeding up the production of publishable articles. (3)

However, these so-called advantages of the conventional theory come at a cost. Conventional theory constitutes a major narrowing of economic theory-in terms both of subject matter and of method. Before the Hicks-Samuelson revolution, the theory of value had been only one part of economics-certainly an important part, but still only a part. Other substantive areas included money and economic fluctuations, economic growth and development, economic institutions, and economic history. (4) It turned out that these areas of economics, and others, could not be understood purely in terms of the theory of value and that, for them, mathematical modeling was not a fruitful dieoretical method. This narrowing of economic theory has been a major reason for the lack of progress on the big questions of economics, since most of the big questions lie precisely in those areas in which conventional theory offers limited insight.

Responses to the Limitations of Conventional Theory

Economists have responded to the limitations of conventional theory in different ways. One way is denial: the areas of economics not amenable to the application of conventional economic theory are considered uninteresting. (5)

Some economists, however, have persisted in finding such areas interesting, and they have tried to develop particular theories, outside the conventional theory, appropriate to each area. Examples include the new institutional economics, transactions cost economics, public choice theory, and Austrian economics. (6) Such attempts to go beyond conventional theory have been handicapped, however, by the lack of an overall theoretical framework into which they all fit. This limits the development of each by confining it to its own ghetto, outside the mainstream. To escape such ghettoes, some economists have attempted to fit their special theories into the Procrustean bed of conventional theory, with universally poor results. (7)

Yet other economists-in fact, most economists-have responded to the limitations of conventional theory' by turning away from "theory" altogether, embracing instead a largely atheoretical applied econometrics8 Work of this kind, like mathematical modeling, has the advantage of meeting the needs of bureaucratic science: it is technically challenging and, being atheoretical, can largely avoid the issue of whether it is important. (9) However, avoiding that issue has allowed some econometric research to degenerate into "freakonomics"-the application of econometric methods to issues of questionable value' in terms of advancing economics as a science. (10)

Moreover, it is increasingly recognized-and not only in economics-that good statistical work is impossible without an appropriate theoretical framework (see Pearl 2018; Henrich and Muthukrishna 2019). Only in the context of such a framework is it possible to judge whether an empirical question is important or not. And only in the light of theory is it possible to judge whether a statistical result is confirmatory or surprising. This matters, because surprising results are in greater need of further confirmation. (11) Indeed, the atheoretical nature of much statistical work has been a major contributor to the replicability crisis.

These different responses to the limitations of conventional theory have therefore been, at best, only partly successful. What is really needed is a better theoretical framework. As it happens, I have one to offer! I did not set out to develop such a framework. I stumbled on it inadvertently.

How I Discovered an Alternative Theoretical Framework

I was trained as a mathematical theorist. However, from the beginning, I was very' aware of the limitations of conventional theory, and I believed the answer lay in producing better models.11 12 But after many years of attempting to produce such models, I came to realize that better models are not the solution: however good my models were, they provided very little insight into how real-world economies worked.

Then, by chance, I discovered a completely different approach to theorizing. At the time, I was wilting a textbook on financial intermediaries and markets, and I read some financial history as background. I found, however, that financial histoiy offered much more than this: it offered more insight than any amount of mathematical modeling into why different financial institutions existed and what they did. So I switched from mathematical modeling to deliving theory from the observation of actual economies-in effect, a switch from Plato to Aristotle (Herman 2013).

My new method of theorizing might be described as one of "patterns and stories." (13) The first step is to study and observe an economy, or part of an economy, and to search for patterns in the evidence (the evidence may be qualitative as well as quantitative). The economy in question can be a contemporary economy, but historical economies have some advantages: they offer a longer period of observation, greater variation, and relative simplicity of structure. Their greatest advantage, however, is that the evidence is readily available from the extensive work of economic historians. There is much less evidence available for contemporary economies: economics does not value or reward mere description. (14)

The next step is to think of stories that might explain the observed patterns. The theory emerges from these stories. The theory is verbal rather than mathematical, describing and explaining the patterns observed in the historical evidence. Nelson argues that such a theory is nonetheless very much an abstract body of reasoning: "Certain variables and relationships are treated as...

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT