American Silver Inflow and the Price Revolution in Qing China

Published date01 February 2016
Date01 February 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12206
AuthorHongjun Zhao
American Silver Inflow and the Price Revolution in
Qing China
Hongjun Zhao*
Abstract
Employing panel data from the Northern China Plain for the period 1736–1911, this paper tests the
so-called price revolution hypothesis. It finds that American silver inflow played an important role in
raising grain prices when factors such as weather and population are controlled. This role is verified in two
dimensions: the quantity dimension of American silver inflow into China; the value dimension of silver
relative to copper coin and to gold. This paper provides the first econometric test of the so-called price
revolution hypothesis in the 18th and 19th century China and deepens our understanding of the role of
American silver inflow in late imperial times of China.
1. Introduction
Following Columbus’s discovery of America in 1492, Spain discovered one of the
richest and biggest silver ore deposits in Potosi in Upper Peru in 1545 (Clark, 1959, p.
58). After that, thousands of tons of American silver were shipped back to Spain and
it was Spain that first experienced the so-called price revolution during the next one
and a half centuries. Since silver was the main metal currency in Europe at that time,
the price level in many European countries was also greatly affected by the silver
inflow.
Among economic scholarship, Hamilton (1934) was the first study that provided
hard evidence of the causal relationship between American silver inflow and the
Spanish price revolution in the 16th and 17th centuries. Similarly, Brenner (1962),
Fisher (1989) and Hammarstrom (1957) found rich evidence of this causal relation-
ship in 16th and 17th century Sweden, England, Spain, France, Germany and Austria.
However, very few economists tried to apply similar tests in the Chinese case. One
reason is that very little historical and, in particular, numerical data are available in
China. Another is that economists are not certain whether similar mechanisms
worked in China given its distance from Europe. Nevertheless, some economic histo-
rians have done tentative and valuable studies.
For example, Quan (1957) argued that in a unidirectional trade relationship after
the 16th century, Europe imported Chinese tea, silk, spices and porcelain each year,
while it did not export the corresponding industrial goods to China. So Europeans
had to transport American silver to China to compensate for the trade deficit. After
careful analysis of rich price information for grain, silk, cloth, cotton, ginseng, land,
* Hongjun Zhao: School of Finance and Business, Shanghai Normal University, No.100, Guilin Road,
Xuhui District, Shanghai, 200234 China. Tel: +86-21-64324270-222; E-mail: hjzhao2002@163.com. The
author is grateful to two anonymous referees and participants in seminars in SUIBE, SUFE, Fudan Univer-
sity, Shanghai Jiaotong University. Financial support from National Social Science Foundation of China
(14WJ008) and Ministry of Education of China (13YJA90159) is gratefully acknowledged.
Review of Development Economics, 20(1), 294–305, 2016
DOI:10.1111/rode.12206
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT