American Needle and the Future of the Single Entity Defense Under Section One of the Sherman Act

Published date01 September 2011
AuthorNathaniel Grow
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1744-1714.2011.01119.x
Date01 September 2011
American Needle and the Future of the
Single Entity Defense Under Section
One of the Sherman Act
Nathaniel Grow
n
INTRODUCTION
The Sherman Antitrust Act
1
is structured around a fundamental distinc-
tion between concerted and independent action.
2
Specifically, Section One
of the Sherman Act regulates concerted activities between two or more
entities, outlawing ‘‘[e]very contract, combination . . . or conspiracy, in re-
straint of trade,’’
3
a provision which has subsequently been limited to target
only ‘‘unreasonable’’ restraints of trade,
4
namely, those that are ‘‘inher-
ently . . . fraught with anticompetitive risk.’’
5
Meanwhile, the independent
actions of a single firm are addressed by the Sherman Act’s much narrower
Section Two, which only regulates the monopolization, or attempted
monopolization, of an industry.
6
r2011 The Author
American Business Law Journal r2011 Academy of Legal Studies in Business
449
American Business Law Journal
Volume 48, Issue 3, 449–501, Fall 2011
n
Assistant Professor of Legal Studies, TerryCollege of Business, University of Georgia. I wish
to thank Ann Morales Olaza
´bal, Robert Bird, and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful
comments on earlier drafts of this article.
1
15 U.S.C. § 1(2006).
2
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Serv. Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 761 (1984).
3
15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006).
4
See, e.g., Gabriel A. Feldman, The Misuse of the Less Restrictive Alternative Inquiry in Rule of
Reason Analysis,58A
M.U.L.REV.561, 570 (2009) (describing the emerging analysis as finding a
practice unreasonable if there is a less restrictive alternative available).
5
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 768–69 (1984).
6
15 U.S.C. § 2 (2006).
This difference in scope between Sections One and Two of the
Sherman Act carries significant practical implications. Because many
Section One cases are decided under the rule of reasonFa notoriously
‘‘open-ended’’ and subjective standard requiring consideration of a
‘‘multitude of relevant factors’’ to determine whether a particular re-
straint’s pro-competitive benefits outweigh its anticompetitive effects
7
F
the outcome of Section One litigation can be extremely difficult
to predict. As a result, firms may struggle to assess the potential for
antitrust liability with any degree of certainty prior to entering into par-
ticular agreements.
8
Moreover, with its highly burdensome discovery pro-
cess, antitrust litigation under Section One is both extremely expensive
and time consuming.
9
In contrast, litigation under Section Two of the
Sherman Act is significantly rarer
10
and much more difficult for plaintiffs
to win.
11
Despite the practical significance of the distinction between con-
certed and independent action under the Sherman Act, courts have strug-
gled at times to determine whether certain challenged activities properly
fall within the ambit of Section One. For example, courts have disagreed
regarding the applicability of Section One to agreements between separate
legal entities within the same corporate umbrella, such as a parent corpo-
7
Gabriel Feldman, The Puzzling Persistence of the Single Entity Argument for Sports Leagues: Amer-
ican Needle and the Supreme Courts Opportunity to Reject a Flawed Defense, 2009 WISC.L.REV.
835, 898 (noting further that the rule of reason ‘‘has been called the ‘antitrust equivalent of
Chinese water torture.’’’ (quoting In re Detroit Auto Dealers Ass’n, Inc., 955 F.2d457, 475–76
(6th Cir. 1992))).
8
E.g., Maurice E. Stucke, Does the Rule of Reason Violate the Rule of Law?, 42 U.C. DAVIS L. REV.
1375, 1422–29 (2009).
9
Edward D. Cavanagh, Detrebling Antitrust Damages: An Idea Whose Time Has Come?,61TUL.L.
REV.777, 809 (1987). Professor Cavanagh notes that ‘‘[a]ntitrust suits are frequently lengthy,
complicated and costly both in terms of monetary costs, including legal fees and related discovery
expenses, and nonmonetary costs, including dislocation of employees, decline in firm morale and
negative publicity.’’ Id. See also Feldman, supra note 7, at 839 (noting that ‘‘[d]iscovery in antitrust
cases has been referred to as ‘war’ . . . .’’ (quoting Frank H. Easterbrook, Discovery as Abuse,69
B.U. L. REV. 635, 635 (1989))).
10
Karen Jordan, Note, Forming a Single Entity: A Recipe for Success for New Professional Sports
Leagues,3V
AND.J.ENT.L.&PRAC. 235, 237 (2001).
11
See Edward Mathias, Comment, Big League Perestroika? The Implications of Fraser v. Major
League Soccer, 148 U. PA.L.REV. 203, 219–20 (1999) (noting that claims under Section 2 of
the Sherman Act are more difficult to prove than Section 1 claims).
450 Vol. 48 / American Business L aw Journal
ration and its less than wholly owned subsidiary.
12
Similarly, the activities of
joint venturesFentities created by two or more firms for the purpose of
jointly engaging in some economic activity
13
Fcan also pose significant
conceptual difficulty under Section One.
14
On the one hand, joint ventures
will typically operate as, and appear to be, a single firm in the market. On
the other hand, however, joint ventures are often closely managed by
multiple separate, sometimes competing firms, raising the potential for the
sort of collusive activity prohibited by Section One.
The U.S. Supreme Court has only rarely addressed the parame-
ters for distinguishing between unilateral and concerted conduct
under the Sherman Act. Until recently, the Court’s most definitive treat-
ment of the issue came in the 1984 case of Copperweld Corp. v. Independence
Tube Corp.
15
In Copperweld, the Court determined that Section One did
not apply to agreements between a corporation and its wholly owned
subsidiary.
16
The Court reasoned that because the parent corporation
and subsidiary shared a ‘‘complete unity of interest’’
17
Finsofar as the
parent could assert full control over the subsidiary whenever it wantedF
their collusion did not deprive ‘‘the marketplace of the independent
centers of decisionmaking that competition assumes and demands.’’
18
Thus, the two were more properly ‘‘viewed as a single economic
unit.’’
19
Subsequent lower courts have extended the Copperweld ‘‘single en-
tity’’ concept beyond just a parent corporation and its wholly owned sub-
sidiary. For example, courts relying on Copperweld have found that Section
One of the Sherman Act did not apply to alleged collusion between sister
12
See infra notes 68–75 and accompanying text.
13
Herbert Hovenkamp, Exclusive Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy, 1995 COLUM.BUS.L.REV.
1, 2.
14
See Thomas A. Piraino, Jr., The Antitrust Analysis of Joint Ventures After the Supreme Court’s
Dagher Decision,57EMORY L.J. 735, 738–46 (2008) (discussing the various ambiguities in stan-
dards applied to joint venture conduct under the Sherman Act).
15
467 U.S. 752 (1984).
16
Id. at 777.
17
Id. at 771.
18
Id. at 769.
19
Id. at 772 n.18.
2011 / American Needle and the Future of the Single Entity Defense 451

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT