Alternation through Death: Is Gerontocracy an Equilibrium?

AuthorRaul Magni Berton,Sophie Panel
Published date01 December 2018
Date01 December 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/1065912918775251
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/1065912918775251
Political Research Quarterly
2018, Vol. 71(4) 975 –988
© 2018 University of Utah
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1065912918775251
journals.sagepub.com/home/prq
Article
Introduction
This article aims to demonstrate that gerontocracy pro-
duces domestic peace. According to the minimal theory
of democracy, the reason why civil wars are less frequent
in democracies is that opposition parties can expect a
leadership change in a foreseeable future: although they
would be better off in the short run rebelling rather than
complying, they are better off in the long run complying
if they have a reasonable chance of winning the next elec-
tions (Przeworski 1999). In dictatorships, waiting until
the dictator dies is generally much costlier. This waiting
time, however, is shortened when the dictator is old.
Therefore, the risk of domestic conflict should decrease
along with the age of leaders.
This peace-inducing property of aging leaders might
be a reason why, in primitive and agrarian societies,
elderhood was often associated with high status (Flanagan
1989; Posner 1995) and why, in many systems, the chief
is chosen among the oldest men (Simmons 1945; Spencer
1965). Although gerontocracy is classically explained by
social ties acquired with age or on personal characteris-
tics such as wisdom or knowledge (Werner 1981), it has
been recently demonstrated that old rulers are preferred
because they produce alternation in power (Magni Berton
and Panel 2017). This article investigates a further impli-
cation of the latter hypothesis: if elections in democracies
and gerontocracy in autocracies are indeed functional
equivalents, both should have similar effects on political
violence.
A quick glance at history lends some credence to these
intuitions, as many systems became more stable as they
started institutionalizing gerontocracy. In Venice, most
elected officials were selected for a fix term in office
except for the Doge who was elected for life (Tullock
2002): as a consequence, Doge entered office at age
sixty-eight on average—compared with thirty-three for
European kings during the same period (Eisner 2011).
This combination of mechanisms for limiting incum-
bency has proven fairly stable on the long run, since
Venice experienced few coups or interfamily wars in its
several centuries of existence (Tullock 2002, 252). In the
contemporary period, the USSR experienced widespread
political unrest under Stalin, who took power at age forty-
four, but violent contestation declined under his succes-
sors, who entered office at age sixty-two on average.
During the post-Stalin era, the two oldest Soviet leaders,
Andropov (sixty-eight) and Chernenko (seventy-three)
both had short but peaceful tenures, which ended with
their natural death; the youngest, Gorbachev (fifty-four)
was removed by a coup.
Beside this anecdotal evidence, the relationship
between leaders’ age and internal conflicts has never been
systematically investigated. Although leaders are increas-
ingly considered as one of the main units of analysis in
international relations (Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza
775251PRQXXX10.1177/1065912918775251Political Research QuarterlyMagni Berton and Panel
research-article2018
1Université Grenoble Alpes, France
2Sciences Po Grenoble, PACTE, France
3Sciences Po Bordeaux, Centre Emile Durkheim, France
Corresponding Author:
Sophie Panel, Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, 11 allée
Ausone, F-33607 Pessac, France.
Email: sophie.panel@scpobx.fr
Alternation through Death: Is
Gerontocracy an Equilibrium?
Raul Magni Berton1,2 and Sophie Panel3
Abstract
According to minimalist theories of democracy, the reason why civil conflicts are less frequent in democracies is
that opposition parties can reasonably expect to win the next elections: they then prefer to wait than to rebel. In
dictatorships, waiting until the dictator dies is generally much costlier. This waiting time, however, is considerably
shortened when the dictator is old. Therefore, the risk of domestic conflict should decrease along with the age of
autocratic leaders. Based on 160 countries from 1960 to 2008, our empirical analysis shows that the leader’s age
decreases the likelihood of violent rebellion in dictatorships, but not in democratic regimes.
Keywords
political leaders, dictatorship, intrastate conflict, democracy

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT