Aiding refugees, aiding peace?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12461
AuthorM. Christian Lehmann
Published date01 September 2020
Date01 September 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:16871704. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
|
1687
Received: 6 August 2019
|
Accepted: 12 June 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12461
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Aiding refugees, aiding peace?
M. Christian Lehmann
Department of Economics, University of Brasilia, Campus Universitario Darcy Ribeiro, Brasilia, DF, Brazil
Correspondence
M. Christian Lehmann, Department of
Economics, University of Brasilia, Campus
Universitario Darcy Ribeiro, Brasilia, DF
70910900, Brazil.
Email: clehmann@unb.br
Abstract
I add two novel features to the twoplayer contest
model, the workhorse model of civil war: civilians
can flee (i.e., become refugees) and refugees receive
aid. I find that aid to refugees can promote peace or
fuel conflict, depending on the context.
1|INTRODUCTION
One strand of literature contends that foreign aid fuels civil war by increasing the pool of
resources that can be captured by armed groups, fostering a war economy, and increasing the
prize of capturing the state (henceforth prize theory).
1
Another strand argues that foreign aid
can mitigate conflict by strengthening a government's military capacity to fight insurgents
(military capacity theory).
2
Furthermore, aid may win hearts and mindsof civilians, leading
them to cooperate with the government, which can reduce conflict by increasing the effec-
tiveness of counterinsurgency (heartsandminds theory).
3
The latter may backfire, however,
because it entices insurgents to sabotage aid delivery to avoid that civilian opinion sways against
them (sabotage theory).
4
I study an additional (so far neglected) mechanism: aid's effect on emigration. I add two
novel features to the twoplayer contest model, the workhorse model of civil war
5
: civilians can
flee (i.e., become refugees) and refugees receive aid. The basic setup of the model consists of two
players contesting a territory. The prize of a military victory is rents”—pecuniary (e.g., taxes,
1
For example, see Besley and Persson (2011), Nunn and Qian (2014), and Bluhm, Gassebner, Langlotz, and
Schaudt (2016).
2
For example, see Collier and Hoeffler (2002), De Ree and Nillesen (2009), Nielsen, Findley, Davis, Candland, and
Nielson (2011), and Ahmed and Werker (2015).
3
For example, see Berman, Shapiro, and Felter (2011) and Beath, Christia, and Enikolopov (2016).
4
See Crost, Felter, and Johnston (2014).
5
See, for example, Haavelmo (1954), Hirshleifer (1988), Hirshleifer (1989), Garfinkel (1990), Grossman (1991),
Skaperdas (1992), Hirshleifer (1995), Fearon (2008), and Besley and Persson (2011).
looting, etc.) and/or nonpecuniary (e.g., imposing a certain religious doctrine)that the contest
winner can extract from civilians.
My analysis highlights that aid to refugees can decrease the prize (hence incentives to fight),
for three reasons: first, it entices fleeing, thus reducing the number of rent payers; second, it
forces players to reduce rent extraction to make fleeing less attractive; finally, it increases the
wage that players must pay their fighters (for rational fighters desert and flee if their expected
utility as refugees are higher). Yet, in some contexts, aid to refugees can also increase the prize
(hence incentives to fight), for example, when it entices civilians to flee and abandon their
assets (e.g., land).
Conversely, aid to civilians in the disputed territory can increase the prize (hence incentives
to fight) by increasing civilians' opportunity cost of fleeing, thus increasing the number of rent
payers.
6
For prize theories, my findings imply that aid to the disputed territory can fuel conflict, not
only because aid is a prize worth fighting over (the main argument of prize theories), but also
because it entices civilians to stay (my argument) hence increasing the number of rent payers. It
may also imply that the heartsandminds mechanism could be less effective in contexts where
aid entices civilians to stay.
7
Finally, for sabotage theories, my results imply that sabotage is less
likely to occur in contexts where successful aid delivery entices civilians to stay.
2|MINIMAL MODEL
The starting point of my analysis is the twoplayer contest model, the workhorse of the
formal conflict literature.
8
Two competing players
i
1,
2
, for example, the government and
an insurgent, represented by their respective leader(s), fight to gain control over some
territory with either pecuniary (taxes, looting, etc.) or nonpecuniary objectives (e.g., im-
posing a certain religious doctrine), that is, to extract rents of some sort from civilians. The
probability of military victory is increasing in the size of a player's army and decreasing in
the size of the other player's army. A player maximizes expected profit (expected rents
minus fighter wages) by choosing the optimal size of its army. My main departure from the
conventional contest model is to relax the assumption that civilians cannot avoid taxation
and that the tax rate is exogenous. In my model, a player must carefully choose the tax rate
because civilians flee if it is too high.
6
In practice, the lion's share of aid goes to conflict countries. For example, Nunn and Qian (2014) compile panel data
containing annual aid receipt and conflict data for 125 countries from 1971 to 2006. Using their data, I estimate that a
country with an ongoing civil war receives, on average, 140% more US food aid and 171% more aid from other donor
countries than a nonconflict country, even after controlling for recipient country GDP per capita, population, and
region. On the other hand, refugees receive comparatively little aid, which starts with the reluctance of many countries
to admit refugees (Lehmann, 2019), followed by opposition to giving them pecuniary forms of aid (e.g., Dahlberg,
Edmark, & Lundqvist, 2012; Dustmann, Vasiljeva, & Piil Damm, 2018 exploit exogenous variation in the allocation of
refugees to Swedish and Danish municipalities, and both find negative effects on residents' support for redistribution;
Vasilakis, 2018 reports similar results for Greece).
7
On the one hand, aid increases civilians' cooperation with the government's counterinsurgency efforts, yet by enticing
civilians to stay it also increases the number of rent payers hence the insurgent's prize. This may explain why existing
empirical evidence for the heartsandminds theory is based mainly on aid in the form of infrastructure (e.g., roads),
which is arguably a less compelling reason to stay than, for example, humanitarian aid.
8
See, for example, Haavelmo (1954), Hirshleifer (1988), Hirshleifer (1989), Garfinkel (1990), Grossman (1991), Skaperdas
(1992), Hirshleifer (1995), Fearon (2008), and Besley and Persson (2011).
1688
|
LEHMANN

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT