Agricultural Subsidies and Farm Consolidation

Published date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12151
Date01 May 2016
Agricultural Subsidies
and Farm Consolidation
By TRACI BRUCKNER
ABSTRACT. Although agricultural subsidies were begun during the
New Deal to provide enough income to enable farmers to continue
operating, their net effect has been to raise the price of farmland and to
squeeze many owner-operated farms out of existence, leaving mostly
large-scale operations that are often tied to agribusiness. Numerous
efforts have been made, with limited success, to mitigate this problem
by limiting the subsidy to small or mid-size farm operations. The 2014
farm bill, adopted by the U.S. Congress, made the situation worse.
Rather than imposing stricter limits on subsidies to the largest farms, the
legislation removed existing limits, ended direct payments, and
increased subsidies for insurance against crop losses and income risk.
The new law not only provides a windfall to owners of very large
farms, it also encourages plowing of fragile soils, since the risks of crop
failure are now borne primarily by taxpayers. The article concludes by
offering recommendations about how to correctthese problems
Introduction
For over three decades, a number of rural organizations, along with
U.S. Senators and Representatives, have sought to reform federal farm
subsidies. The impetus for those reforms has been the negative impacts
that virtually all federal farm subsidies have on beginning farmers, and
on small and mid-sized farms. In particular, many advocates for reform
have argued that when subsidies are unlimited, they provide the
nation’s largest farms the financial resources to bid up land prices and
drive their smaller neighbors out of farming.
Senior Policy Analyst at the Center for RuralAffairs since 2001. B.A. (Political Science/
Sociology)from Wayne State College.Farmed near Osmond, Nebraska from 1994 to 2006.
Served multiple terms on the Organizing Committee of the National Sustainable Agricul-
ture Coalition, including a term as chair. Also served two terms on the USDA Advisory
Committeeon Beginning Farmers and Ranchers,including one term as chair.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 75, No. 3 (May, 2016).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12151
V
C2016 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
Setting a limit, or cap, on federal farm program payments is an issue
that has been around since at least the late 1970s. It has always been con-
troversial, with support and opposition most often breaking along the
lines of northern farm states versus southern farm states rather than along
partisan lines. Historically, southern farm states, especially ones dominated
by large cotton or rice growers, opposed limits on the program payments.
Northern states, particularly in the Great Plains, had a history of small-
scale, independent farming and thus favored limits on the scale of farming.
On the other hand, major farm interests with a predominantly northern
constituency, such as the National Corn Growers Association, have no
desire to see any cap on program payments to large farms (Law 2003).
At its heart, however, the fight over farm payment limits has always
been a philosophical disagreement about the purpose of farm pro-
grams. The opponents of payment limits have argued that the system
should reward the efficiency of large farms. The proponents of capping
payments, by contrast, have primarily been advocates of healthy rural
institutions. They have always believed that federal farm subsidies
should support small and mid-sized family farms, and that a strong,
effective payment limit is necessary to keep subsidies from being used
by the nation’s largest farms to drive up land prices.
The 2002 Commission on Payment Limits
The 2002 farm bill called upon the U.S. Department of Agriculture
(USDA) to create the Commission on the Application of Payment Limita-
tions for Agriculture. The purpose was to study how existing payment
limits ($75,000 per person on marketing assistance loan gains and loan
deficiency payments) might be better administered, and whether to
make any changes in the structure of limits applied to agricultural pay-
ments (U.S. Commission on Payment Limits 2003). Secretary of Agricul-
ture Ann Veneman named USDA chief economist Keith Collins as
chairperson. The Commission consisted of 10 members, three appointed
by the Senate Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition, and Forestry; three
appointedbytheHouseCommitteeonAgriculture; three appointed by
the Secretary of Agriculture; and the USDA chief economist.
The Commission members appointed by the Senate included Neil
Harl, Ames, Iowa; Ellen Linderman, Carrington, North Dakota; and Terry
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology624

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT