Agricultural Interest Groups in Danish Politics: an Examination of Group Frustration Amidst Political Stability

Date01 September 1968
AuthorWilliam E. Laux
Published date01 September 1968
DOI10.1177/106591296802100307
Subject MatterArticles
436
AGRICULTURAL
INTEREST
GROUPS
IN
DANISH
POLITICS:
AN
EXAMINATION
OF
GROUP
FRUSTRATION
AMIDST
POLITICAL
STABILITY
WILLIAM
E.
LAUX
Colorado
State
University
ANISH
POLITICS
are
customarily
described
as
stable,
ideal,
and
placid.
D
Nevertheless
in
May
1961
the
principal
Danish
farmers’
organizations
M ~
instituted
a
virtually-complete
&dquo;production
stop&dquo;
for
the
purpose
of
pres-
suring
the
government
to
accede
to
their
demands.
This
resort
to
&dquo;direct
action&dquo;
in
Danish
politics
was
little
noticed
by
either
Danish
or
outside
political
scientists
Yet
an
understanding
of
why
Danish
farmers
felt
constrained
to
adopt
exceptional
and
extra-legal
measures
can
be
valuable
for
the
student
of
comparative
politics.
Why
did
the
&dquo;stop&dquo;
occur
in
Denmark
where
political
bargaining
has
been
facilitated
by
the
absence
of
sharp
class
distinctions;
a
native
preference
for
prag-
matic
political
results;
the
relatively
few
contentious
issues
in
modern
Danish
poli-
tics ;
the
homogeneity
of
Danes
as
regards
their
language,
religion,
and
culture;
and
the
comparatively
small
size
of
the
country
and
population?
How
does
one
account
for
&dquo;direct
action&dquo;
tactics
in
a
political
system
which
achieved
a
remark-
ably
peaceful
transition
to
constitutionalism
in
1849,
has
firmly
adhered
to
parlia-
mentarianism
since
its
establishment
in
1901,
and
has
sustained
a
multi-party
system
with
four
dominant
parties
which
have
nearly
always
been
able
to
work
con-
structively
together?
The
highly
atypical
behavior
of
Danish
farmers
in
1961
provides
an
oppor-
tunity
to
shed
some
light
on
those
factors
which
may
motivate
important
interest
groups
to
take
matters
into
their
own
hands
despite
the
existence
of
a
pronounced
traditional
emphasis
upon
the
norms
of
negotiation
and
compromise.
This
study
concludes
that
the
&dquo;stop&dquo;
was
produced
by
the
dysfunctional
convergence
of
several
developments
in
Danish
politics
which
momentarily
rendered
Danish
&dquo;consensual&dquo;
norms
inoperative.2
2
These
dysfunctional
developments
behind
the
imposing
sta-
bility
of
Danish
politics
suggest
the
need
for
a
better
understanding
of
political
NOTE:
Grants
from
the
Faculty
Improvement
Committee,
Colorado
State
University,
and
the
Faculty
Research
Committee,
Western
Kentucky
State
University,
helped
make
this
study
possible.
1
Political
science
as
an
academic
discipline
has
been
sorely
neglected
in
Denmark.
The
first
significant
steps
towards
introducing
political
science
into
Denmark
were
undertaken
at
the
University
of
Aarhus
in
1960.
Very
little
literature
in
English
is
available.
Note-
worthy
are
Ben
A.
Arneson,
The
Democratic
Monarchies
of
Scandinavia
(New
York:
Van
Nostrand,
1949);
Dankwart
A.
Rustow,
"Scandinavia:
Working
Multi-party
Systems"
in
Sigmund
Neumann
(ed.),
Modern
Political
Parties
(Chicago:
U.
of
Chi-
cago
Press,
1956),
pp.
169-93;
John
T.
Bernhard,
"Empirical
Collectivism
in
Den-
mark,"
Journal
of
Politics,
13
(November
1951),
623-46;
Neil
Elder,
"Parliamentary
Government
in
Scandinavia,"
Parliamentary
Affairs,
13
(Summer
1960),
363-73;
and
Kenneth
E.
Miller,
"The
Danish
Electoral
System,"
Parliamentary
Affairs,
18
(Winter
1964-65),
71-81.
2
Gabriel
A.
Almond
refers
to
the
"consensual"
nature
of
the
relations
between
groups
and
parties
in
Scandinavia
in
his
"Research
Note:
A
Comparative
Study
of
Interest
Groups
in
the
Political
Process,"
American
Political
Science
Review,
52
(March
1958),
276.
437
adjustment
in
advanced
political
systems,
especially
the
impact
of
changing
political
conditions
upon
dominant
economic
interest
groups.
I
The
agricultural
interest
groups
Much
of
the
character
of
present-day
Denmark
is
traceable
to
the
freed
Danish
peasants
of
1788.
In
the
early
part
of
the
nineteenth
century,
thanks
to
the
Education
Act
of
1814
and
through
the
efforts
of
Bishop
N.
F.
S.
Grundtvig
and
Kristian
Kold
who
established
the
renowned
Danish
folk
high
school
movement,
the
former
serfs
were
provided
with
a
social
awareness
and
cultural
identity.3
Throughout
the
nineteenth
century
the
peasants
gradually
made
the
transition
from
tenancy
to
independent
farm
ownership.
The
transformation
of
the
peasants
into
a
socially
alert,
economically
independent,
and
literate
class
occurred
just
in
time
to
enable
them
to
meet
successfully
the
challenge
of
the
loss
of
two-fifths
of
the
Danish
realm
during
the
1864
Prusso-Danish
War
and
acute
agricultural
crises
encountered
in
the
1870’s
as
a
result
of
the
breaking-out
of
grain-producing
areas
abroad.
The
farmers
were
faced
with
the
choice
of
either
calling
for
protective
tariffs
or
revising
radically
their
system
of
production
away
from
the
growing
of
grain
for
export.
They
chose
the
latter
by
converting
to
the
concentrated
manufac-
ture
of
animal
husbandry
products
of
the
high
and
controlled
quality
for
which
Denmark
has
long
been
renowned
4
The
modern
Danish
agricultural
interest
groups
were
built
upon
the
farm
cooperatives
and
agricultural
associations
(landboforeninger)
which
the
farmers
formed
to
meet
the
technical
and
economic
problems
involved
in
the
above-
mentioned
conversion
of
their
production
system.5
In
1893
the
various
regional
landboforeninger
were
amalgamated
into
the
Federation
of
Danish
Agricultural
Associations
(De
Samvirkende
Danske
Landboforeninger,
hereafter
referred
to
as
DSL).
In
1963
DSL
had
a
membership
of
139,248
farmers
with
units
ranging
in
size
from
about
twenty-five
to
two
hundred
acres.&dquo;
A
closely
related
interest
group
is
the
Agricultural
Council
(Land brugsraadet,
hereafter
referred
to
as
LR)
which
was
formed
in
1919.
LR
is
a
&dquo;peak&dquo;
association
which
represents
DSL,
the
farm
cooperative
movement
of
about
500,000
members,
and
various
agricultural
export
committees.
Politically,
the
awakened
medium-sized
farmers
of
the
1840’s
played
an
impor-
tant
role
in
the
peaceful
establishment
of
constitutionalism
in
1849.
The
Local
Government
Act
of
1841
greatly
stimulated
the
farmers
towards
political
activity.
In
the
decades
after
1849
the
farmers
organized
their
own
political
party,
Venstre,
and
fought
the
battle
against
Hejre
for
parliamentarianism
which
was
finally
won
3
On
the
folk
high
schools
see
Peter
Mannische,
Denmark,
A
Social
Laboratory
(Copenhagen:
G.
E.
C.
Gads,
1939),
pp.
74-135.
4
The
story
has
been
told
many
times.
A
reliable
account
may
be
found
in
Einer
Jensen,
Dan-
ish
Agriculture
(Copenhagen:
J.
H.
Schultz,
1937),
chapters
III,
VI,
and
XII.
5
There
is
no
concise
history
of the
landboforeninger.
For
the
farm
cooperatives
see
Henning
Ravnholt,
The
Danish
Cooperative
Movement
(Copenhagen:
Det
Danske
Selskab,
1947).
6
Beretning
1963-64
De
Samvirkende
Danske
Landboforeninger,
p.
7.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT