Aggregate Concentration, Turnover, and Mobility among the Largest Manufacturing Firms in Japan

Published date01 December 1987
AuthorTomio Iguchi
DOI10.1177/0003603X8703200404
Date01 December 1987
Subject MatterEconomic
The Antitrust Bulletin/Winter 1987
Aggregate concentration, turnover,
and mobility among the largest
manufacturing firms in Japan
BY TOMIO IGUCHI*
I.
Introduction
939
Economists
and
policy makers have long been interested in
aggregate concentration measures
of
economic power.
The
level
of
aggregate concentration is measured by
the
share
of
the
economic activity
that
is attributable to
the
largest firms. The
relevance
of
aggregate concentration is a subject
of
debate in
economic literature, especially in the area
of
industrial organiza-
tion.
The
controversy focuses on whether there is any meaning
attached to concentration measures
that
are
not
related to indi-
vidual markets.IPolitical
and
sociological concern over aggregate
concentration as the index for economic democracy was rising
throughout
this controversy. The economic importance
of
aggre-
Ryukoku University, Kyoto, Japan.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: Iam grateful to W. S. Comanor, A. Grabel, S.
Akutagawa, the editor
of
this journal, and anonymous referees,
for
helpful comments and suggestions.
Of
course, the remaining errors are
solely my own responsibility.
1See, e.g., D. Duke,
"Trends
in Aggregate Concentration," FTC
Working Paper no. 61 (June 1982), pp. 1-2.
© 1988by Federal Legal Publications. Inc.
940 The antitrust bulletin
gate concentration also became increasingly prominent with the
emergence of a conglomerate merger wave or enterprise diversifi-
cation. These factors obscured the traditional market boundaries
and dimmed the concept
of
market concentration. Aggregate
concentration has become requisite as a complementary concept
to measure the degree
of
competition in the market:
In Japan, where there are interlocking financial and manage-
rial ties among firms, aggregate concentration is a more impor-
tant measure
of
economic power than in other countries. The
close interfirm relationship, consisting of manufacturing and
financial firms and general trading companies, is called a "busi-
ness group" in Japan.' There are four Zaibatsu (literally, wealth
clique)
groups-Mitsui, Mitsubishi, Sumitomo, and Fuyo
groups-
and two non-Zaibatsu principal bank
groups-Sanwa
and
Daiichi-Kangyo groups. These are known as
"the
six major
business groups." Each group has its own presidents' club. The
member firms of the six major business groups number 182
companies as of March
1982.
These firms are tied together by
means of reciprocal shareholding, lender-borrower and buyer-
seller relationships, and reciprocal hiring of executives, etc.'
The findings
of
the Federal Trade Commission and Bureau of
the Census indicate that aggregate concentration has remained
almost unchanged in the United States manufacturing sector
2See, for studies of business groups in Japan, R. E. Caves and M.
Uekusa, Industrial Organization in Japan (The Brookings Institution,
1976), pp. 59-87; A. Goto, "Business Groups in a Market Economy,"
European Economic Review 19 (September
1982):
53-70; and
I.
Naka-
tani,
"The
Economic Role of Financial Corporate Grouping," in The
Economic Analysis
of
the JapaneseFirm, ed. M. Aoki (North-Holland,
1984), pp. 227-58.
3In 1981, 73 percent of the number of affiliates
of
the six major
business groups employed executives (directors and auditors) dispatched
from other affiliates
of
their own groups. In 1981, 20 percent
of
the to-
tal loans of the member firms of the six major business groups was com-
posed of loans from their groups' financial institutions. See Japanese
Fair Trade Commission, On the Situation
of
Business Groups (1983).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT