Agency Input as a Policy-Making Tool

AuthorJosé D. Villalobos
DOI10.1177/0095399712438378
Date01 September 2013
Published date01 September 2013
Subject MatterArticles
Administration & Society
45(7) 837 –874
© 2012 SAGE Publications
DOI: 10.1177/0095399712438378
aas.sagepub.com
438378AAS45710.1177/009539971243
8378VillalobosAdministration & Society
© 2012 SAGE Publications
1University of Texas at El Paso, USA
Corresponding Author:
José D. Villalobos, Department of Political Science, University of Texas at El Paso, Benedict Hall
111, 500 W. University Avenue, El Paso, TX 79968, USA.
Email: jdvillalobos2@utep.edu
Agency Input as a
Policy-Making Tool:
Analyzing the Influence
of Agency Input on
Presidential
Policy Success in
Congress
José D. Villalobos1
Abstract
This study posits a theoretical framework for understanding the role and
value of agency input in presidential-legislative policy making. The author as-
serts that by using agency input for policy development, presidents instill
their proposals with a degree of bureaucratic objectivity, expertise, process
transparency, and agency support, which aids their legislative passage while
lowering the extent of changes made to policy substance in the process. To
test his hypotheses, the author conducts binar y and ordered logistic regres-
sion analyses using pooled cross-sectional data across 12 administrations
from 1949 to 2010. The author finds that agency input serves as a key com-
ponent for increased presidential-legislative success.
Keywords
President, agency input, policy making, Congress
Article
838 Administration & Society 45(7)
When presidents take the lead in the policy-making process, they hold the
potential to influence three stages: policy development, agenda setting (i.e.,
the policy proposal stage), and the legislative outcome. Although scholars
have long considered how presidents can influence the policy-making pro-
cess at the proposal and legislative outcome stages, relatively fewer studies
have explored the policy development stage. To help fill this gap in the litera-
ture, I address the development phase of the policy-making process by con-
sidering how presidents can best manage and develop their policy initiatives
using agency input to maximize their policy performance in the legislative
arena. Understanding this issue is important because whether and to what
extent presidents can achieve their policy goals largely depends on their abil-
ity to propose their initiatives in a manner that Congress will be willing to
enact them.
In this study, I posit that agency input affords presidential policy develop-
ment with added measures of bureaucratic objectivity, expertise,1 process
transparency, cooperative consultation with legislators, and agency support,
each of which imbue presidential proposals with a measure of bureaucratic
legitimacy that strengthens a president’s legislative policy performance. To
test my hypotheses, I conduct a series of binary and ordered logistic regres-
sion analyses using pooled cross-sectional data on presidential-legislative
proposals covering the period 1949 through 2010. I find that agency input,
among other factors, serves as a key component to increased presidential-
legislative policy success, both with respect to policy outputs and outcomes.
In light of these findings, I prescribe a new policy-making strategy with
agency input at its core that builds on previous knowledge concerning presi-
dential-bureaucratic management and its impact on legislative policy
making.
Centralized Policy Making Reconsidered
In their managerial role, presidents may look to White House staffers or the
vast resource of executive departments and agencies for assistance to help
develop their policy proposals. Carrying out this process requires that presi-
dents effectively collect, organize, and sort out information. As Neustadt
(1990) puts it, “a president is helped by what he gets into his mind. His first
essential need is information” (pp. 128-129). In general, presidents have at
their disposal two primary resources for policy making: the “responsive com-
petence” of White House personnel and the expertise of agency civil servants
(see Heclo, 1999; Moe, 1985; Rourke, 1992; Rudalevige, 2002; Wolf, 1999).
To manage the process, presidents may centralize policy development within
Villalobos 839
the Executive Office of the President (EOP), delegate its formation to the
wider bureaucracy (i.e., decentralize), or use some combination of the two
(Rudalevige, 2002).2
When presidents seek information for policy development, they may
experience a measure of friction, which scholars commonly refer to as a
“transaction cost” (Coase, 1937, 1990; Milgrom & Roberts, 1990; North,
1990; Williamson, 1979, 1998; Williamson & Masten, 1995; see also Hall &
Taylor, 1996, p. 951; Epstein & O’Halloran, 1994, 1999). Friction may occur
when presidents, in seeking information to develop their policy proposals,
encounter opposing viewpoints and contradictory interests espoused by an
assortment of executive branch personnel, be they from the outer agencies/
departments or the EOP.
To minimize transaction costs, presidents often seek the cheapest source
of trusted information to help them develop their policy proposals (Rudalevige,
2002). In doing so, presidents typically aim to maximize the value of a policy
proposal in terms of their own policy leanings. As such, scholars find that
when faced with the option of centralizing the development of a policy pro-
posal within the White House staff or delegating its development to executive
agency actors, presidents generally prefer to centralize the process whenever
possible as it lowers the front-end managerial transaction costs and maxi-
mizes their personal policy preferences (see Moe, 1985; Moe & Wilson,
1994; Nathan, 1983).
Torn between high public expectations for policy performance and a lim-
ited amount of formal authority within a fragmented and fractious political
system, a president’s preference for centralization may be seen as an institu-
tionally rational, if not ultimately effective, approach to take (Moe, 1985,
1989). Given the post-1930s growth of the executive branch, it makes intui-
tive sense that presidents increasingly focus their policy activities around the
White House Office and larger EOP. However, little systemic quantitative
work has explored the extent to which presidents have used varying sources
of information for policy development or the relative impact of such informa-
tion on presidential performance in the legislative arena.
Although a large literature has helped unearth major insights on presiden-
tial efforts to cope with and manage the development and institutional growth
of the modern presidency (e.g., Burke, 2000; Dickinson, 1997; Moe, 1985;
Ragsdale & Theis, 1997; Walcott & Hult, 1995, 2005), this area of research
has been mainly dominated by case studies that are not systemically general-
izable. Furthermore, relatively few studies have addressed directly the merits
of centralization in presidential policy development. One exception is
Rudalevige’s (2002) study, which provides the first major quantitative

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT