Aftermarket Monopolization: The Emerging Consensus in Economics

AuthorLorenzo Coppi
DOI10.1177/0003603X0705200104
Date01 March 2007
Published date01 March 2007
Subject MatterArticle
THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol.52, No. l/Spring 2007 :53
Aftermarket
monopolization:
the emerging consensus in economics
By
LORENZO
COPPI*
The
accepted
economic
definition
of
aftermarket
is
provided
by
Shapiro
and
Teece
and
entails
two
characteristics:
"(1)
the aftermarket
product
or service is
used
together
with
a
primary
product,
and
(2)
the
aftermarket
product
or service is
purchased
after
the
primary
product."I
There is a significant
body
of literature discussing the economics
of aftermarket competition. Especially after
Kodak?
the economic liter-
ature
has debated at length
whether
anticompetitive effects are likely
to arise from
the
supplier of a
primary
good
monopolizing the after-
market
for
its
product.
The
concern
is
that,
having
obtained
or
defended
amonopoly in
the
aftermarket for its product, a
supplier
of
a
primary
good
would
be able to charge a
supra
competitive aftermar-
*Vice President, CRA
International,
Washington, DC.
Carl
Shapiro
&
David
J.
Teece, Systems
Competition
and Aftermarkets: an
Economic
Analysisof Kodak, 39
ANTITRUST
BULL.
135 (1994).
Eastman
Kodak
Co. v.
Image
Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
For
economic
commentaries
of
the
case, see
Carl
Shapiro,
Aftermarkets and
Customer
Welfare:
Making
Sense
of
Kodak,
63
ANTITRUST
L.J.
483 (1995);
Steven
C.
Salop,
The First Principles Approach to Antitrust at the Millennium, 68
ANTITRUST
L.J.
187 (2000);
and
Dennis
W.
Carlton,
A
General
Analysis of Exclu-
sionary
Conduct
and
Refusal
to
Deal-Why
Aspen
and
Kodak
areMisguided, 68
ANTITRUST
L.J.
659 (2001).
©2007 by
Federal
Legal
Publications, Inc.
54 : THE
ANTITRUST
BULLETIN:
Vol.52, No. l/Spring 2007
ket price to its consumers. The discussion
in
the
economic literature
typically focuses on
whether
a
primary
good
supplier
would
find it
profitable to charge asupracompetitive aftermarket price to its cap-
tive installed base, given the possible resulting loss of sales of the pri-
mary
good
(and
associated
loss of
future
aftermarket
sales).' Two
competing
views have been
put
forward
in
this regard: the Chicago
view,
which
maintains
that
it is unlikely
that
a
primary
good
supplier
would
find it profitable to exploit its
installed
base;
and
the
post-
Chicago view,
which
contends that, in general,
primary
good suppli-
ers
have
an incentive to raise prices to their installed base.
It
is
now
established
that
in theory,
even
under
fairly general cir-
cumstances, the potential for
harm
from aftermarket monopolization
is present.
It
is also clear
that
the
source of
the
potential for anticom-
petitive
harm,
i.e., the
manufacturer's
incentive to exploit its installed
base,
may
be present even
when
the
primary
market
is quite competi-
tive
and
consumers
are fully informed
about
costs
over
the entire life
of the
primary
product
(lifecycle cost).'
However, significant debate remains on
the
likelihood
and
signifi-
cance of
such
theoretical potential. The conclusion is that acase-by-
case
investigation
is
needed
in
order
to
determine
whether
In
addition
to
the
literature focused on
aftermarket
competition, there
are
at least
two
strands
of the economic literature
that
are
relevant to this dis-
cussion. First is
the
economic literature
on
competition
between
systems of
complementary
products.
See,
e.g., Michael L. Katz &
Carl
Shapiro, Systems
Competition
and Network
Effects,
8 J.
ECON.
PERSPECTIVES
93 (1994);Stanley M.
Besen &
Joseph
Farrell,
Choosing
How to
Compete:
Strategies
and
Tactics
in Stan-
dardization, 8 J.
ECON.
PERSPECTIVES
117 (1994);
and
Joseph
Farrell &
Garth
Saloner, Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, 16
RAND
J.
ECON.
70
(1985). Second is
the
large economic literature
on
bundling
and
foreclosure.
See,
e.g., Michael D. Whinston, Tying,
Foreclosure,
and
Exclusion,
80 AM.
ECON.
REv.
837 (1990);
and
Dennis Carlton &Michael Waldman, The
Strategic
Useof
Tying to
Preserve
and
Create
Market Power in Evolving Industries, 33
RAND
J.
ECON.
194 (2002).
The
lifecycle cost includes
the
original
purchase
price of the
equip-
ment,
but
also
expected
maintenance
costs,
including
supplies,
parts,
and
service
over
the useful life of the
product
(e.g., a
car's
lifecycle cost includes
the
purchase
price, fuel, maintenance,
and
insurance,
but
excludes the sal-
vage value).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT