After Dodd-Frank

AuthorJ. Nicholas Ziegler,John T. Woolley
Published date01 June 2016
Date01 June 2016
DOI10.1177/0032329216638061
Subject MatterArticles
Politics & Society
2016, Vol. 44(2) 249 –280
© 2016 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329216638061
pas.sagepub.com
Article
After Dodd-Frank: Ideas
and the Post-Enactment
Politics of Financial Reform
in the United States
J. Nicholas Ziegler
Brown University
John T. Woolley
University of California, Santa Barbara
Abstract
The financial crisis of 2008 raised the politics of regulation to a new level of practical
and scholarly attention. We find that recent reforms in U.S. financial markets
hinge on intellectual resources and new organizational actors that are missing
from existing concepts of regulatory capture or business power. In particular,
small advocacy groups have proven significantly more successful in opposing the
financial services industry than existing theories predict. By maintaining the salience
of reform goals, elaborating new analytic frameworks, and deploying specialized
expertise in post-enactment debates, smaller organizations have contributed to a
diffuse but often decisive network of pro-reform actors. Through the rule-writing
process for macroprudential supervision and derivatives trading, these small
organizations coalesced with other groups to form a new stability alliance that has
so far prevented industry groups from dominating financial regulation to the degree
that occurred in earlier cases of regulatory reform.
Keywords
financial crisis, implementation, capture, knowledge regime, macroprudential
regulation, derivatives
Corresponding Author:
J. Nicholas Ziegler, Watson Institute, Brown University, 111 Thayer Street, Providence, RI 02912, USA.
Email: j_ziegler@brown.edu
638061PASXXX10.1177/0032329216638061Politics & SocietyZiegler and Woolley
research-article2016
250 Politics & Society 44(2)
The financial crisis of 2008 elevated the analytic priority of the politics of financial regu-
lation. The literature on regulation has been dominated by the concepts of business
power and the possibility of regulatory capture. Contrary to other major reforms, where
public attention subsided quickly after the enactment of new laws, attention to the goals
of the Dodd-Frank reforms has been sustained. The ability of incumbent firms to domi-
nate the rulemaking process has been blocked in important ways by the emergence of a
new network of interested organizations. As we show in this paper, the changing land-
scape of regulation is shaped above all by a consensus around a set of key ideas and
policy objectives that stand in stark contrast to previously dominant views.
Passed in July 2010, the Dodd-Frank Act1 resulted from the Obama administration’s
primary effort to craft a thoroughgoing regulatory reform for financial markets. Even
before taking office in January 2009, the Obama team was under intense pressure to
supplement the taxpayer-funded bailouts of 2008 with more lasting regulatory changes.
The reform effort was an important part of managing public anger over the bank bailouts
of October 2008. In addition, the Obama team emphasized reform in order to preserve a
measure of U.S. leadership in international efforts to reduce the risk of financial turmoil.
Revamping the existing regulatory institutions was second only to health care legislation
in the new administration’s priorities. Signed by the president in July 2010, the Dodd-
Frank Act was hailed as the most far-reaching overhaul of the country’s financial structure
since the Great Depression. Yet many observers, and much of the press, fear the reforms
are being diluted in the implementation process through industry efforts, that they have
been “captured” by the very interests the legislation was intended to constrain.2
Social scientists have also become attuned to the risk that general interest reforms
can be eroded even after legislative passage.3 Contrary to the image of Dodd-Frank as
a well-intended reform that has been subverted by powerful business interests, we
argue that the implementation of the law requires a different understanding of post-
enactment politics based on a broadened view of business power. We do not claim—
nor do the most optimistic observers we have encountered—that the Dodd-Frank
reforms can assuredly prevent financial crises in the future. It is too early to gauge the
ultimate success of the legislation. Yet in the implementation process to date, regula-
tors have used their new statutory powers to take many actions contrary to the explic-
itly and strongly expressed preferences of the financial services industry. These actions
have imposed significant new costs and limits on industry.
These developments do not mean the financial industry has been tamed.4 Rather,
they mean the post-enactment politics of financial reform are, like the politics of
enactment, contingent on an evolving set of coalitions that exploit the procedural fea-
tures of the rulemaking process to advance their goals. To understand this process, we
need a framework quite different from the stark images of regulatory capture and busi-
ness power that have informed the literature so far.
The fluidity of coalitions and ideas that we document was itself informed by a chang-
ing international context. Because the global financial crisis quite clearly originated in
the United States, top U.S. officials sought to lead the international effort to regulate
financial markets more closely. Policymakers in Europe, particularly Germany,
Ziegler and Woolley 251
portrayed the Anglo-American penchant for light-touch regulation as a central cause of
the crisis.5 In response, the United States claimed the role of committed if imperfect
regulatory pacesetter in the key postcrisis meetings of the G20 leaders in 2008 and
2009.6
Although international pressures made U.S. leaders more supportive of regulatory
reform, they do not explain the domestic maneuvering among the groups and organi-
zations that wanted to shape the reform measures in the United States. Accordingly,
this article focuses analysis on the political strategies of the groups and advocacy
organizations that shaped the implementation of new rules within the United States.
We therefore examine how domestic actors used several types of resources includ-
ing the ability to sustain an issue in the public eye, the articulation of coherent guiding
ideas and principles, the capacity to find allied, if not formally coordinated actors, as
well as to bring material resources or positional advantages to bear on key decision
makers. This approach requires an altered understanding of capture. It implies that
business can activate sources of power beyond those described by the contrast between
instrumental versus structural power. In particular, the financial services industry pro-
vides not only discrete products for its customers, but also produces a body of expert
knowledge on which regulators depend as they seek to supervise market competitors.
The concepts, frameworks of analysis, and tools supplied by the financial services
industry can, over time, grow into a coherent “knowledge regime.”7 When uncontested
in the post-enactment process of rulemaking, the industry’s ability to shape the pre-
vailing knowledge regime becomes a significant form of political power that can deci-
sively alter the regulatory process. Our argument for these underlying changes in the
politics of reform relies on three main assertions.
First, the financial crisis was the culmination of a thirty-year period of deregulatory
policy that fundamentally altered the underlying principles as well as the competitive
boundaries of the finance industry. The deregulatory program from the 1970s to 2008
made financial services ever more central to the U.S. economy. This broad-ranging
shift, often termed “financialization,”8 had the effect of permitting more concentration
in certain financial markets while encouraging competition in others. As a result, the
customary mechanisms of regulatory capture were slowly transformed. Instead of
privileging incumbent firms by creating entry barriers that protected them from com-
petition, federal regulatory agencies increasingly exposed firms to competition and
accepted arguments from free-market principles, moving away from prescriptive rules
toward greater reliance on industry self-regulation.
Second, by changing the basis of regulatory capture from entry-barrier mechanisms
to a diffuse but pervasive sort of intellectual capture, the deregulatory interregnum
from 1977 to 2007 had cross-cutting effects. It made the industry more dependent on
widespread acceptance of its central role in the country’s economic life. At the same
time, the pervasive role of finance made the industry increasingly vulnerable to intel-
lectual challenge and popular rejection. The shift to new forms of regulatory capture
opened the door to policy entrepreneurs and activists who questioned the principles of
market self-regulation in finance. Once the crisis of 2008 revealed the potentially dis-
ruptive fragility of core financial markets—in securitized mortgages, short-term

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT