Advances of the 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines in the Analysis of Competitive Effects

DOI10.1177/0003603X9303800302
Date01 September 1993
AuthorPaul T. Denis
Published date01 September 1993
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust BulletinlFall1993
Advances
of
the 1992 Horizontal
Merger Guidelines in the analysis
of
competitive effects
BY PAUL T.
DENIS·
479
When viewed from the antitrust perspective, some mergers are
considered "bad," while other mergers are considered "good," or
at least "not bad." What is it that separates the bad mergers from
the rest? What is it that we fear will happen if the bad mergers are
not blocked? More formally, what are the potential adverse com-
petitive effects
of
concern that define the objectives of antitrust
merger enforcement?
Perhaps the most significant contribution
of
the new Horizon-
tal Merger Guidelines, issued jointly by the Department of Justice
*Partner, Arnold &Porter, Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: Revised and extended from remarks made at the West-
ern Economics Association 67th Annual International Conference Con-
temporary Policy Issues Session: The 1992 Merger Guidelines: View from
the Inside, San Francisco, California, July 11, 1992. This article benefited
greatly from discussions with the other panelists as well as comments
from Tom Baker and Robert Willig. None
of
the above bear responsibility
for
what remains.
Ii) 1993 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
480
The antitrust bulletin
(001)
and the Federal Trade Commission
(FfC)
, is to clarify the
answer to these questions and to present aframework for distin-
guishing
the
bad
from the rest.' In doing so, the 1992 Guidelines
continue
the
efforts
of
the 1982 and 1984 versions
of
the
DOJ
Guidelines and the 1982
FfC
Statement on Horizontal Mergers to
move
away from
"merger
analysis by the
numbers"
and toward a
more
complete
analysis considering not only market concentration
but
also
other
market
factors
relevant
to the
likely
effect
of
a
merger.
This article reviews the prior treatment
of
competitive effects
and the relationship between market concentration and competi-
tive
effects
in
the
Supreme
Court
decisions
and
enforcement
agency guidelines before outlining the analytical framework artic-
ulated by the 1992 Guidelines.
I.
Early
Supreme
Court
precedent
The
antitrust treatment
of
mergers is governed by section 7
of
the
Clayton
Act, which was amended in 1950 to
prohibit
stock
and asset acquisitions where
"the
effect
of
such acquisition may
be
substantially
to
lessen
competition,
or
tend
to
create
a
monopoly."2
Left
to the courts were the tasks
of
identifying
the
adverse
competitive
effects
of
concern
(the
ways
in
which
a
merger
might
substantially lessen
competition)
and
determining
Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal
Merger Guidelines (April 2, 1992), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH)
~
13,104 [hereinafter 1992 Guidelines]. The analysis of the 1992 Guide-
lines builds on the framework of the 1982 Guidelines and their 1984 revi-
sions. See Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (June 14, 1984),
reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH)
~
13,103 [hereinafter 1984 Guide-
lines] and Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (June 14, 1982),
reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH)
~
13,102 [hereinafter 1982 Guide-
lines].
215 U.S.c. §18. Mergers may also be evaluated under section 1 of
the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §I, or section 5 of the Federal Trade Com-
mission Act, 15 U.S.C. §45, but the standards under those statutes have
converged to the section 7standard. See United States v. Rockford
Memorial Corp., 898 F.2d 1278 (7th Cir. 1990).
Competitive effects: 481
how to distinguish mergers in which those effects were likely
from mergers in which those effects were not likely. The tasks
were enormous and seemingly unbounded. But after the wide-
ranging congressional debate, the statutory language offered the
courts at least two points
of
guidance:
(1)
Congress chose to pro-
hibit only those mergers with adverse competitive effects, as dis-
tinguished from mergers with adverse sociopolitical effects and
(2) Congress did not choose to ban all mergers in concentrated
markets or all mergers
significantly
increasing
concentration;
Congress prohibited only those likely to lessen competition.
The Supreme Court was slow to respond to the tasks left to it
by the amended law. Only twice in nine opinions did the Court
articulate a view of the competitive effects of concern. The com-
petitive effects focus
of
antitrust merger analysis has evolved over
the last 30 years from a fear
of
concentration in and
of
itself to a
fear
of
specific postmerger conduct. But whatever the competitive
effect of concern was, analysis of market concentration data was
somehow central to distinguishing mergers likely to have adverse
effects from those unlikely to have such effects.
In
Brown
Shoe, the Supreme Court's first horizontal merger
decision after the adoption
of
the revised Clayton Act in 1950, the
Court never articulated what might happen as a result
of
amerger
that might lead to a lessening
of
competition. The
closest
the
Court came to articulating the competitive effects
of
concern was
paraphrasing the statute, referring to section 7 as a "tool for pre-
venting
all
mergers
having
a
demonstrable
anti
competitive
effect."! By contrast, the Court noted, the legislative history was
clear that section 7 was not intended to impede
for example, amerger between two small companies to
enable
the
combination
to
compete
more
effectively
with
larger
corporations
dominating the relevant market. nor a merger between acorporation
which is financially healthy and a failing one which no longer can be a
vital competitive factor in the market.'
3Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. 294, 319 (1962).
4Jd.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT