Advance Market Commitments for R&D in Diseases That Disproportionately Affect Low‐Income Countries

Published date01 July 2012
Date01 July 2012
AuthorEbenezer Kwabena Tetteh
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1747-1796.2012.00442.x
The Journal of World Intellectual Property (2012) Vol. 15, no. 4, pp. 280–303
doi: 10.1111/j.1747-1796.2012.00442.x
Advance Market Commitments for R&D in Diseases
That Disproportionately Affect Low-Income
Countries
Ebenezer Kwabena Tetteh
University College of London
There has been a growing focuson finding ways to increase the availability of beneficial health technologies for
the diagnosis, treatment, prevention, elimination and eradication of neglected diseases that disproportionately
affect low-income countries.A number of interventions have been suggested but one mechanism thatappears to
have gained favour is advanced market commitments (AMCs), which has been piloted with the pneumococcal
conjugate vaccines. AMCs aim to inflateand reduce the uncertainty around the stream of expected quasi-rents
provided by (uninsured)healthcare demands in low-income countries to encourage private pharmaceutical and
biotechnology firms to undertake the desired R&D investments. This paper evaluates the potential of AMCs
to increase the supply of new molecular entities (NMEs) for neglected diseases and notes that AMCs are the
appropriate instruments as long as the global community relies (wholly or in part) on private firms to make
systematic ratherthan piecemeal public service or philanthropic investments. It calls fora review of World Trade
Organization (WTO)’s Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) agreement to explicitly recognize
the inadequacies of intellectual property rights (IPR) and patent protectionin stimulating innovation and access
to health technologies for neglected diseases.
Keywords AMCs; neglected diseases; pharmaceutical R&D; TRIPS
One of the key challenges facing international health is reducing the portion of global disease burden
attributable to neglected diseases that afflict almost exclusively low-income populations. The health
problems posed by neglected diseases can be traced to a whole range of issues including poorly
performing or non-existent healthcare delivery systems,human rights violations, civil strife, political
instability and non-healthcare determinants of health (agriculture and nutrition, housing, female
education and transportation etc.) that determine individuals’ self-efficacy to withstand random
shocks to their health (Hotez and Thompson, 2009). According to Musgrove and Hotez (2009),
improvedsanitation and water supply alone could reduce schistosomiasis and guinea wormmorbidity
by 75% and that of blinding trachoma by 25%. Putting aside these general public health policy
issues uncovers the more specific problem of limited availability of health technologies for neglected
diseases.1
In their seminal paper, Trouiller et al. (2002) reported that 16 of 393 new molecular entities
(NMEs) marketedbetween 1975 and 1999 were for tropical diseases and tuberculosis.Indeed, over the
study period, it was 13 times more likelythat a new therapeutic molecule will be developed for cancer
and diseases of the central nervous system than for a neglected tropicaldisease. Following this study,
Kaplan and Laing (2004) reported that only 10% of global pharmaceutical R&D expenditures are
directed towardshealth problems that makeup 90% of the global disease burden, creating the so-called
(10/90) pharmaceutical or innovation gaps. More recently, Cohen et al. (2010) revisited the Trouiller
et al. (2002) study and using the same counting methodology but different definitions for neglected
diseases, found that between 1975 and 1999, 32 NMEs were actually marketed. This, however, does
280 C2012 Blackwell PublishingLtd
Advanced Market Commitments for Neglected Diseases Ebenezer Kwabena Tetteh
not change the general conclusions that these diseases are neglected in terms of R&D investments. As
reported by Vanderelst and Speybroeck (2010), neglected diseases are less researched compared to
matched global diseases with similar disability-adjusted life years. Averaged over time,the number of
publications on matched global diseases was four times higher in the PubMed database and six times
higher in Webof Science. Solving the problem of limited R&D investments will require surmounting
the various hurdles that privately funded pharmaceutical and biotechnology innovators (hereafter
private firms) face irrespective of whether they are dealing with global or neglected diseases. These
hurdles include (1) the state of basic research and underlyingscience to support translational/applied
research; (2) economic hurdles that determine the profitability and hence the willingness of private
firms to make R&D investmentsover long periods of time during which no cash flows are realized; (3)
regulatoryhurdles that ensure the outputs of R&D investments are fit forhuman use; and (4) problems
associated with violations of international regimes of intellectual property rights (IPR) and patent
protection (Webber and Kremer, 2001). However, what makes neglected diseases notably different
from global diseases is that the expected R&D pay-offs commensurate with the lower aggregate
economic demand in low-income countries offers limited or non-existent scope for recouping the
costs of R&D effort.
As low-income countries in aggregate constitute a relatively small segment of the global mar-
ket, private firms rationally focus on profitable (global) diseases common to high- and low-income
nations. Lichtenberg (2005) notes that the quantity of pharmaceutical R&D conducted globally
is positively correlated with the burden of disease in high-income countries but not the disease
burden in low-income countries. This reflects not just their low incomes per capita but also the
absence of health-insurance protection to subsume the financial risks of unpredictable health-
care demands and make income transfers to the sick, especially in time periods where health-
care expenses are unaffordable relative to disposable household incomes. For the same reasons,
it is unlikely that domestic pharmaceutical and biotechnology firms in low- and middle-income
countries with innovation capacity will invest in neglected diseases when the profit potential is
sub-optimal relative to that in global disease categories—unless government intervention redi-
rects their investment choices. Lanjouw and MacLeod (2005) report from a survey conducted
in 2003, that, at most, 10% of total R&D expenditure by the largest pharmaceutical firms op-
erating in India (both Indian-owned and multinational subsidiaries) was spent on developing-
country diseases. That said the problem of low market profitability also undermines R&D in global
diseases.
Trouiller et al. (2002) report that almost 40% of candidate therapeutic molecules under inves-
tigation in R&D portfolios of private firms (mostly based in the United States) are abandoned as
effective global demand for these molecules are expected to generate sub-optimal on-patent cash
flows. Candidate molecules under investigation are abandoned not only for clinical efficacy and
safety concerns but also out of commercial considerations. Indeed, Acemoglu and Linn (2004) show
that a 1% increase in the potential market size of a therapeuticcategory leads to 4–6% increase in the
number of therapeutic molecules in that category. Finkelstein (2004) also show that health policies
that create higher expected demand by encouraging wider use of existing vaccines have dynamic
effects of increasing R&D investments (specifically a 2.5-fold increase in the number of new vaccine
clinical trials). The author argues that for every $1 increase in annual expected market revenue for
vaccines stimulates, annually, an additional $0.06 in discounted present value (PV) of expenditures
on new clinical trials. A similar dynamic effect is reported by Civan and Maloney (2009) who found
that the higher the retail price of existing drugs that have no generic competitors (a proxy of the
expected price of a new drug) in a given therapeutic category, the higher the number of drugs in the
development pipeline for that therapeutic category. Holding disease incidence and severity (a proxy
C2012 Blackwell PublishingLtd
The Journal of World IntellectualProperty (2012) Vol. 15, no. 4 281

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT