Addressing Climate Change With a Comprehensive U.S. Cap-and-Trade System

Date01 August 2009
Author
39 ELR 10752 ENVIRONMENTAL LAW REPORTER 8-2009
A R T I C L E
Addressing Climate Change
With a Comprehensive U.S.
Cap-and-Trade System
by Robert N. Stavins
Robert N. Stavins is the Albert Pratt Professor of Business and Government at the John F. Kennedy School
of Government, Harvard University, and a University Fellow at Resources for the Future.
I. Introduction
e impetus for a mea ningful U.S. climate policy is grow-
ing. Scientic evidence has increased (Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change, 2007a, b), public concern has been
magnied, and many people perceive what they believe to be
evidence of climate change in progress. Such concern is rein-
forced by the aggressive positions of key advocacy groups,
which are no longer limited on this issue to the usual environ-
mental interest groups; religious lobbies, for example, have
also been vocal. is has been reected in greatly heightened
attention by the news media. e overall result is that a large
and growing sha re of the U.S. population now believes that
government action is warranted (Bannon et al., 2007).
In the absence of federal policy, regions, states, and even
cities have moved forward with their own proposals for
policies intended to reduce the emissions of carbon dioxide
(CO2)and other greenhouse gases. Partly in response to fears
of a fract ured set of regional policies, a n increasing number
of large corporations, sometimes acting individually, and
at other times in coalitions—together with environmental
advocacy groups—have announced their support for serious
national action. Building upon this is the April 20 07 U.S.
Supreme Court decision that the Administration has the leg-
islative authority to regulate CO2 emissions,1 as well as ongo-
ing pressure from European and other nations for the United
States to re-establish its international credibility in this realm
by enacting a meaningful domestic climate policy.
us, momentum is clearly building towards the enaction
of a domestic climate-change policy. But there should be no
mistake about it—meaningful action to address global cli-
mate change will be costly. is is a key “inconvenient truth”
that must be recognized when policymakers construct and
1. Massachusetts et al. v. Environmental Protection Agency et al., No. 05-1120,
argued November 29, 2006, decided Apr. 2, 2007.
evaluate proposals, because a policy’s specic design will
greatly aect its ability to achieve its environmental goals, its
costs, and the distribution of those costs.
ere is general consensus among economists and policy
analysts that a market-based policy instrument targeting
CO2 emissions—and potentially some non-CO2 green-
house-gas (GHG) emissions—should be a central element of
any domestic climate policy. is is reected in international
assessments of national policy instruments, as well (Intergov-
ernmental Panel on Climate Change, 2007c). While there
are trade os between two alternative market-based instru-
ments—a cap-a nd-trade system and a carbon t ax—the best
and most likely approach for the short to medium term in the
United States is a cap-and-trade system.
It is critical to identify the most eective, lowest-cost, and
most equitable policy design at t he outset, because any pol-
icy design once in place can be dicult to change (Repetto,
2007). e environmental integrity of a domestic cap-and-
trade system for climate change ca n be maximized and its
costs and risks minimized by: targeting all fossil-fuel-related
CO2 emissions through an upstream, economywide cap;
setting a trajectory of caps over time that begins modestly
and gradually becomes more stringent, establishing a long-
run price signal to encourage investment; adopting mecha-
nisms to protect against cost uncertainty; and including
linkages with the climate-policy actions of other countries.
Importantly, by providing the option to mitigate economic
impacts through the distribution of emission allowances, this
approach can establish consensus for a policy that achieves
meaningful emission reductions.
It is for these reasons and others that cap-and-trade sys-
tems have been used increasingly in t he United States to
address an array of environmental problems, including the
phase-out of leaded gasoline in the 1980s, the reduction of
sulphur dioxide (SO2) and nitrogen oxide (NOx) emissions
from power plants beginning in 1995, and the phase-out of
chlorouorocarbons (CFCs) (Stavins, 2003).
O R  E
P 298 (2008) and is reprinted with permission.
Copyright © 2009 Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, DC. reprinted with permission from ELR®, http://www.eli.org, 1-800-433-5120.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT