ACTIVITY STRATEGIES, AGENCY PROBLEMS, AND BANK RISK

AuthorDung V. Tran,Pascal Louvet,Isabelle Girerd‐Potin,M. Kabir Hassan
Published date01 August 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12216
Date01 August 2020
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XLIII, No. 3 Pages 575613 Fall 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jfir.12216
ACTIVITY STRATEGIES, AGENCY PROBLEMS, AND BANK RISK
Dung V. Tran
Saigon International School of Business, Banking University Ho Chi Minh City
M. Kabir Hassan
University of New Orleans
Isabelle GirerdPotin
Univ. Grenoble Alpes, Grenoble INP, CERAG
Pascal Louvet
Univ. Grenoble Alpes, Grenoble INP, CERAG
Abstract
We investigate whether diversification affects bank risk taking in the U.S. banking
industry, and whether this relation is partially explained by agency theory. Our
results show that U.S. banks with a relatively high share of noninterest income
become riskier when moving toward noninterestincomegenerating activities,
especially activities from investment banking, proprietary trading, and so on.
Diversification not only affects conditional average risk, but also the dispersion of
risk. Moreover, diversified banks that received assistance from the Troubled Asset
Relief Program (TARP) become riskier than diversified nonrecipients after TARP
capital injections. Our main findings are robust to a battery of robustness tests. The
results are partially explained under agency frameworks related to poor corporate
governance.
JEL Classification: G21, G28, G34, G38
I. Introduction
The banking industry is a particularly important sector in our economy, serving as a
channel through which disruptions in its smooth functioning could translate into
adverse fluctuations in the real economy. A sound banking system is a primary
objective of regulators and policy makers. In response to the recent financial crisis
along with the adjustments of capital adequacy, liquidity requirements, or mandatory
stress testing of systemically important financial institutions, financial regulators are
considering structural bank regulation measures, which aim to review and eventually
limit the scope of activities that banks can offer (Gambacorta and Van Rixtel 2013).
Historically, banks face strict restrictions on business lines and suffer high
competition pressures from nonbanks on both sides of the balance sheet, leading to
return and risk problems (Saunders and Cornett 2008, chap. 21). This heavyhanded
regulation assumes the return to stability of the banking system, but at the cost of
575
© 2020 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
inefficiency and poor innovation (Dewatripont, Rochet, and Tirole 2010). Since the
1970s, these restrictions have been attenuated along with the wide deregulation of
financial markets. Banks are increasingly allowed to expand to activities previously
prohibited and now provide onestop shopping for a number of consumer services
(DeYoung and Rice 2004). They diversify their income stream into new activities such
as investment banking, venture capital, trading securities, and other activities that
generate noninterest income, and they traditionally earn profit from lending activities
in the form of interest income. Beyond deregulation, technological progress as well as
financial innovation spur banks to further diversify. This integration of new
nontraditional business lines into existing business activities consequently changes
the allocation of bank capital and riskreturn preferences. The financial crisis of
20072009, with the failure of many banks and the ensuing economic recessions,
unveiled the dark side of functional diversification. Consequently, various initiatives
such as the Volcker Rule in the United States, Vickers in the United Kingdom,
Liikanen in the European Union,
1
and the recent call for the 21stcentury
GlassSteagall Act propose narrow banking policies that aim to limit some of the
permissible activities of banks. This assumes that these activities contribute to higher
riskiness in banks. In line with this view, banks should concentrate on their main and
traditional activities.
Meanwhile, whether from a theoretical perspective or empirical studies, how
diversification affects bank risk taking has been a contentious debate among financial
economists over the past two decades (see Sanya and Wolfe 2011; DeYoung and
Torna 2013). However, these studies ignore the agency problem that can derive the
relation between diversification and bank risk taking. Therefore, the main objective of
this study is twofold: (1) how diversification affects bank risk taking and (2) how the
agency problem affects the relation between diversification and bank risk taking.
Theoretically, there are conflicting predictions about whether the potential
benefits from the diversification of activities outweigh the costs. On the one hand, it is
generally believed that a combination of activities reduces the total risk of diversified
banks (e.g., Brewer 1989). The conventional wisdom is that noninterestgenerating
activities are considered noncorrelated, or at least weakly correlated, with interest
generating activities, resulting in a coinsurance effect, diversification gains, a more
stable revenue stream (DeYoung and Roland 2001), and a reduced bankruptcy risk
(Saunders and Cornett 2008). Additionally, assuming an absence of agency conflicts
between banks and borrowers, Diamond (1984) argues that diversified banks can
enhance their credibility in their loanmaking decisions and their borrowers
monitoring by overcoming information asymmetry between depositors and borrowers.
Diversified banks can retrieve clientsinformation during the loan decisionmaking
process and profitably reuse it for noninterestincomegenerating activities such as
securities underwriting or insurance (e.g., Yasuda 2005; Bharath et al. 2007). In turn,
information from noninterestgenerating activities can facilitate loanmaking decisions
and make them more efficient, thus improving credit risk management. Diamond
1
Please see Casu et al. (2016) for the detailed differences between these initiatives.
576 The Journal of Financial Research
(1984) also suggests that diversified banks have a more stable credit supply under
aggregate shocks, which may in turn lead to lower volatility of cash flow from loan
portfolios. We call this channel the diversificationstability channel.Evidence from
Litan (1985) and Brewer (1989), among others, lends support to this channel by using
U.S. bank data. DeYoung and Torna (2013) suggest that U.S. banks with a higher share
of noninterest income experience a lower probability of failure. Using international
data, Elsas, Hackethal, and Holzhäuser (2010) show that diversification positively
affects bank profitability and market valuations, whereas Sanya and Wolfe (2011)
document that diversification decreases insolvency risk and improves bank profitability
in emerging countries.
On the other hand, little research is concerned that certain nonbank activities
may be riskier than traditional banking activities when viewed on a standalone basis
(Saunders and Walter 1994). Securities underwriting is an example. In a firm
commitment security offering, the underwriters profit (i.e., the spread between the
underwriters buy price and the public offer price) is capped, whereas the downside
risk could be much higher. The extent of the diversification gains depends on the
comovement of income streams generated from combined activities (DemirgüçKunt
and Huizinga 2010). If the soughtafter activity is inherently riskier than the banking
business and these activities are highly correlated,
2
the cost of diversification could
outweigh the benefit, leading to a higher risk for banks (Boyd, Graham, and
Hewitt 1993). Increased diversification of activities does not translate into risk
reduction if there is a lack of expertise in the newly adopted business (Jiménez and
Saurina 2004). In their theoretical model, Shleifer and Vishny (2010) show that with
a shift toward nontraditional activities, banks are more likely to enlarge their balance
sheets and transmit security market fluctuations into the real economy; the volatility
of sentiment turns into the volatility of real activity through the banking sector.
They suggest that this type of profitmaximizing behavior may induce the instability
of the banking sector. Diversification raises the concern of intensified agency
problems because functional diversification can increase a bankssizeaswellasits
opaqueness, leading to discretionary decisions to undertake valuedecreasing
investments (Berger and Ofek 1995). We call this channel the diversification
fragility channel.Demsetz and Strahan (1997) examine the stock returns of banks
during 19801993 and indicate that better diversification does not translate into risk
reduction. Similarly, DeYoung and Roland (2001) document a greater volatility of
bank earnings with a move toward feebased activities during 19881995. Stiroh
(2004) and Stiroh and Rumble (2006) find diversification benefits from moving
toward noninterestincomegenerating activities, but these gains are offset by
increased exposure to noninterest activities. Avraham, Selvaggi, and Vickery (2012)
describe the typical structure of a large bank holding company (BHC) and
complexity of noninterestgenerating activities and reasons for diversification. De
Jonghe (2010) finds that diversification increases the tail beta of European banks,
2
Bhattacharyya and Purnanandam (2011) document a substantial increase in systematic risk and decreased
idiosyncratic risk in banking during 20002006.
577Activity Strategies, Agency Problems

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT